nm1128: as always er you know if you want to discuss the essays with me come along you know any time or certainly i'll be in my room during s-, so-called surgery hours [laugh] right let's get this thing moving i'm dealing with the economics of er free trade areas which some of you have done i mean i'll be doing it a little bit more depth than we did on my other course but there's obviously quite a bit of overlap on this particular topic so i'm looking for you to do the lecture rather than me er so here's the handout i assume you've got all sm1129: nm1128: yes [laughter] we're doing a little bit more [laughter] i i said you're doing the lecture [laughter] but some people haven't had the privilege of er doing the E-U in developing countries so what i'm dealing with is that today we'll deal with the the economics of customs union and free trade agreements and in next week we'll deal with article twenty-four which is the W-T-O er article the general agreement on tariffs and trade article er which covers authorizes er free trade areas and customs union because of course they fundamentally break article one er the principle of non-discrimination i mean the whole purpose of a free trade area or a customs union is to discriminate in favour of the partner countries and therefore against the world er so which is entirely against the whole essence of the GAT the er agreements and the W-T-O so article twenty-four permits this major break er from the principle of non-discrimination but i'll deal with that next week er 'cause it's a topic which er has come to the fore particularly given the proliferation of er these preferential trade agreements as Bhagwati prefers to call them er i mean at the moment i think there's about a hundred- and-six preferential trade agreements have been notified to the W-T-O and not all agreements are notified er so there's something in n-, in excess of a hundred-and-six preferential trade agreements er and the p-, as i say the previous past ten years or less have seen a proliferation of these agreements er i mean everybody's signing agreements as if there was no tomorrow er which is entirely contrary to all that we were saying about the Uruguay round and the move towards a rules based system for international trade and the principle of non-discrimination that underpins all of the new er international economic order so one of the questions really i mean one of the fundamental questions which people are asking themselves today is why you know why in a world in which on the one hand we strengthened the general agreement on tariffs and trade and we have the general agreement on trade and services and trade related intellectual property rights agreements trade related investment measures er and so on i-, particularly the strengthening of the di-, the er dispute settlement process all of that you know we we emphasized really was to underpin the spectacular growth of world trade that we've seen er so why at this time of all times do we see this huge increase in the number of preferential trade agreements which is fundamentally based on mercantilist philosophy isn't it i mean the view that you know we sign up agreements between ourselves er and keep out the rest of the world you know we sort of concentrate the gains from trade er between us at the expense of or partly at the expense of the rest of the world so why that's one of the big questions that we'll continue to come to to come back to er i don't think anybody knows the answer to that one er but we can at least speculate on it and of course as Bhagwati puts it as well are they are they obstacles to the development of a non-discriminatory free trade world or are they simply stepping stones which might be the apologist case if you like for customs unions and free trade agreement stepping stones in the sense that er you first of all er free up trade between the partner countries and maybe deepen relations between you er and having adjusted to that you can then go on to er free trade on a worldwide basis and particularly perhaps for developing countries er that might be very attractive rather than go suddenly for broke you know suddenly when your barriers to trade as we've discussed in the past have been very high very high tariff and non- tariff barriers er and you you know rapidly take them away over a short period of time expose yourself to world trade that's a pretty frightening thought er for for any country so maybe a regional free trade agreement particularly with an industrialized country a large industrialized country like United States or a regional grouping like the E-U that might be a sort of stepping stone so you free trade first of all with the the big industrialized market and you adjust to that and then you go in to er liberalized trade on a on a worldwide basis and that's the sort of optimistic view if you like of er the role of free trade agreements er in which case they're stepping stones to er er final free trade or are they obstacles in the way that i indicated at the beginning they might be 'cause fundamentally they're discriminatory and the more agreements you have the more discrimination we have in the world and therefore we're running quite contrary to the fundamental principle of the W-T-O principle of non-discrimination so that's the big debate and we there's no answers to that one you just have to really make up your own minds so first of all let's go through with the basic economics of it i say my apologies to those who've done this before but it's such an important topic it comes up in all sorts of areas er so what i'm going to do is er put up the diagrams and then get those of you particularly well anyone but particularly those of you who've done E-U and developing countries course er to then explain the diagrams to me rather than me do it so let's see if we when we get this thing focused in this ghastly room that we have least it's not as bad as the Palmer building is it where you've got the the screen up one end and people are sitting up the other end i mean that is really truly awful okay well the starting point on the analysis of er preferential trade agreements really was by put up by Jacob Viner er who pointed out that er preferential trade agreements on the one hand freed up trade between the partner countries and therefore the theory of comparative advantage can work okay but of course it was only partial liberalization er it discriminated against the countries and so it was er Viner who coined the terms trade creation and the next diagram that we'll do trade diversion er have we got a spare handout oh you do right sm1130: nm1128: okay so trade creation then this is comparative advantage working mm but of course only between the member countries mm er this diagram here er this is a preferential trade agreement between a developing country right which is er labelled L-B-C here and the European Union E-U er and we're looking to see what happens in the developing country here er the the argument's a general one but er purposes of our interest let's look at the developing country side of the equation er now in this case here the European Union is the cheapest source of supply er of the imported goods okay the rest of the world the dearer source of supply somewhere up here so we can forget about them okay so we're simply we're importing from the E-U er which is the cheapest source of supply prior to the preferential trade agreement there is the tariff tariff is the distance between P-star-E-U and P-E-U here okay so that's the that's the height of the tariff er and prior to the preferential trade agreement we're importing M-O from the E-U tariffs then disappear okay and er we then er expand our imports from the E-U upto M-F-T-A imports under the free trade agreement mm okay first of all first question for you er how do consumers gain from this in the di-, in terms of the diagram what can you show has been the gain in welfare to consumers from signing the free trade agreement yeah sm1131: can provide them choice not very good price nm1128: right sm1131: goods nm1128: right sm1131: his prices and a wider choice of foreign goods nm1128: okay so they pay a lower price er than before mm and they've got a wider choice of goods there's something else purely analytical terms sm1132: C-N-D nm1128: sorry sm1132: C-N-D sm1133: nm1128: okay so they pay a a lower price for the previous level of imports M-F- T-A er sorry M M-O right but then also what happens because the price falls what else happens sm1132: consume more nm1128: they they consume more that's right and there's the wider choice which you said we'll come back to that one later on we're just dealing with a particular product just now so they gain in two respects they gain that the previous level of imports they can buy cheaper than before mm and then because the goods are cheaper they move down their demand curve okay er consuming even more mm so the gain in the consumer surplus is this area in here someone just define for me what do we mean by the gain in the consumer surplus it's a technical term in economics what does it mean sm1134: does it mean how much work consumer's doing to pay er difference of how much nm1128: that's right that's right exactly that's a that's a very good definition of it okay so the consumer surplus er is er i mean let's er well let's take a price er er well someone describe to me in terms of the diagram what it means if it's under what you mean maybe i'll leave it to you it's the difference between what people will be willing to pay and what they actually have to pay sm1135: nm1128: sorry sm1135: the price that they're willing to pay s-, that should be the price P-E- star and the that actually pays P-E-U sm1134: P-E-U sm1135: nm1128: right right right okay yes about right so so the consumer surplus then is the increase in the area under the demand curve okay so er that's what i-, if you take any particular level of imports imports M-O okay er they'd be willing to pay as you said P- E- U-star but they actually only have to pay that okay so they gain that about here right and similarly all the way down the demand curve it's only the very last unit that's consumed all right at which the price they have to pay is just equal at the margin is just equal to the price er that they'd be willing to pay for all the intramarginal units they'd be willing to pay a higher price but they don't have to okay they just have to pay price P-E-U okay so the area under a demand curve is the consumer surplus mm and what we're measuring here is the increase in the consumer surplus as a consequence of er the abolition of a tariff area A-B-C-D okay we then divide that up okay er i think it pretty well speaks for itself the loss of tariff revenue of course is by the government in the developing country mm i er going back to what we were talking about this morning if Morocco er signs a free trade agreement or so in-, er indeed it has signed a free trade agreement with the E-U then one major impact on on on Morocco is that previously i think something like twenty per cent of government revenues in Morocco came from import duties most of those were from the E-U about three-quarters of its imports come from the E-U well once the agreement's fully in place that source of government revenue will disappear mm er it's a very important element it's a er a c-, a a very important cost to particularly to developing countries and signing free trade agreement with industrialized countries so that loss of government revenue is the is the size of the tariff P-star against P okay so that's the height of the tariff multiplied by the previous level of imports M-O mm so that's the tariff it used to be applied to imports from the E-U that's now disappeared so the difference between those two prices multiplied by the previous level of imports I-E in the area A-B is the loss of tariff revenue by er Morocco or where it happened to be so that element under the demand curve the increase in the consumer surplus A-B-C-D is made up of two components mm the first one's a pure transfer mm it's a transfer from the government of Morocco to the consumers in Moroco mm so one just cancels out the other all right net er there's no welfare gain in that sense all right there's a gain in consumer surplus but that chunk of the consumer surplus in here is just a decrease in government revenues and that's transferred to consumers through the lower price that they pay for the previous level of imports one balances out the other exactly er zero change in terms of welfare unless you like to say that well it's better off if er consumers gain er than if governments get their revenues but as economists we're we're very neutral in all those things all right er so we don't make value judgements as to whether governments should consume or whether private individuals or firms should consume point of view of the economy that's simply a a transfer er no welfare effect at all so the net welfare effect then is that the two tri-, the is the is the triangle here plus this whatever that shape is i've forgotten my methematics somebody tell me [laughter] er D in there er it's those two areas C- plus-D is the net welfare gain okay so cons-, the gain and the consumer surplus minus this transfer element A-B so we're left with this area in here so that's the welfare gain unambiguously a welfare gain to the developing country from the er abolition of the tariffs the free trade agreement and that's what Viner called trade creation mm the consumers er are able to purchase er a higher level of imports at a lower price let's look a little bit further now er i've sketched in here not terribly well but i hope it's clear what's going on behind the scenes here because this is the demand for imports and the demand for imports is a residual demand mm it's the difference between domestic demand and domestic supply okay that's imports mm 'cause we assume that the good is produced within Morocco within the developing country er as well as imported from the E-U we'll come back to that assumption later but that's the basic assumption it's the same product produced within the er Morocco and also imported so imports are the difference then between domestic demand all right the demand in the developing country and supply in the developing country mm so let's look now at this what lies behind this trade creation gain what are its two components then imports rise for two reasons what are they there's rise in imports in M-O M-F-T-A it's for two reasons what are they sm1132: [cough] the position of tariffs which creates obviously a lower price and er greater consumption nm1128: right okay so that's the movement down the demand curve here okay so the lower price we demand more of something if it's cheaper we buy more of it right that's one component and the second component of the rise in imports how about the left hand side sm1135: nm1128: right okay specifically what's happening the the tariffs taken away so competition sm1132: will destroy the er unproductive er enterprise nm1128: or the less efficient one sm1132: or the less efficient nm1128: the less efficient ones that's right okay so we move back down the supply curve in the developing country okay so we take away the tariff protection okay the the marginal producers then the ones that could only survive under tariff protection now simply go under yeah sm1136: i have just one question er nm1128: o-, sm1136: nm1128: yes i mean you're you're right but but y-, you're sort of jumping the gun as it were you're so you're moving ahead in the in the analysis that is indeed the fear okay that we we've talked about the infant industry arguments the reasons for protection so maybe you shouldn't be signing just yet that's right that's right that's right maybe you know i mean i i showed a pretty steep curve here all right which indicated that they were indeed vulnerable right i deliberately drew that supply curve quite steeply for precisely the reasons you've given okay but there's an awful lot of firms that need the tariff protection because we're dealing with a developing country er they're still learning by doing er things i'll be going onto in a moment on on economies of scale and production you know they they just entered the manufacturing sector fairly recently they're still feeling their way they're still learning skills and they're still moving down their long run average cost curve and so forth er and is suddenly bang the protection's taken away and they go straight down the supply curve here right yeah but we'll come onto that in a a moment that's a good point er so er i've got a situation here then where er the increase in imports is due to two forces the first one is the movement down the demand curve for the product in the developing country something's cheaper you buy more of it the second element is that the doing away with the tariff protection does away with the less efficient producers mm they may be infant industries too bad the infant never grows up all right er er and that's the second reason then why imports rise mm er right let's explore that a little bit further now er given that theory suppose you had er let's go back to last term now okay where we talked about the possibilities of a free trade agreement er well certainly er on on the other course i talked about er a free trade agreement between the E-U and say sub-Saharan African countries mm er so we're talking here about countries particularly er low levels of income low levels of industrialization and the rest given the analysis that we've got there do you think the trade creation i i'm lost to the fact that the E-U as i say is [cough] er you know planning to sign free trade agreements with various regional groupings of these countries er no later than two-thousand-and-eight mm two-thousand-and six two-thousand- and-eight er given then a free trade agreement between the E-U and sub-Saharan African countries do you think the trade creation effects would be large or small sm1135: nm1128: right sm1135: nm1128: so it i-, w-, so so trade creation would be large or small sm1135: large sm1132: small nm1128: ah [laugh] right [laughter] you're saying small [laughter] sm1132: 'cause i think what they were saying that that result result packed in in small trade creation nm1128: because sm1132: well because the sort of fact you got a less developed country er nm1128: mm sm1132: which is sm1136: sm1132: products will what was manufacturing er everything else from the whole production will not be able to compete er against the E-U E-U of their countries producers nm1128: well if if it couldn't compete against it okay all right then following what we've just said just now sm1132: right yeah nm1128: okay there's going to be a big surge in imports sm1132: mm nm1128: that's going to wipe out the local industry okay sm1132: but then again we did mention earlier first term that er it's not just that tariffs nm1128: well all that yes sm1132: not sure whether they're er will be removed or not nm1128: it will oh yes i mean because all all the non-tariff barriers will be reduced as well as the tariffs or at least most of the non-tariff barriers all the import quotas import licensing everything else has to go in a free trade agreement i mean it is free trade all right right we can i mean we can't actually look at the details you have to say well it's not quite as simple as that but let's just keep it at that for the moment because that's more or less what it is but what i'm getting at here though is say we're talking about Chad or Mali right some very very poor countries er you know sm1136: yeah sorry nm1128: the industry that they've got sm1136: this is this is what i thought er nm1128: right sm1136: what it is about is whether the what the E-U c-, could export whether it is suitable for the er er African mark-, er market for Mali for example i mean the Mali er consumer does he really want er a car or does he really want nm1128: well he probably wants it [laughter] sm1136: well he wants a car yeah he wants a car but can he pay for it nm1128: yes yes sm1136: so that that's that's what i was going to nm1128: right sm1136: yeah nm1128: okay sm1136: so nm1128: and in terms of local production then what's what's what sort of goods are going to be produced you know manufactured goods right sm1132: nm1128: right so a lot of the local industry will be producing for the domestic market okay and these goods will be pretty basic consumer goods right fundamentally selling in terms of price okay they're cheap they use local materials local labour er but not exactly state of the art they're not beautifully designed coloured whatever right but they're basic essentials of life in that country er they're you might call them non-tradeable goods a lot of them mm er they are purely produced for the domestic market they might have a regional market but that's tha-, that's another story all right they're certainly not goods that compete with the sort of goods which you'd import from the E-U what sort of goods are you going importing from the E-U if you're Chad Mali et cetera Uganda what what sort of goods are you going to be importing from the E-U capital goods investment goods intermediate products okay not produced in the local economy on the whole that's the key point okay so the key word i'm getting round to then is that one of the important aspects of the trade creation effect is the degree of substitutability between domestic production and imported goods okay in other words my supply curve that i've got here okay er and i've drawn that quite steeply indicating that the degree of substitutability is quite small mm most of the goods you import from the E-U are not produced in the domestic economy so if you like the trade displacing effect on domestic production is also going to be quite small now it depends on the economy right i've talked about Chad or Mali if we're talking about Cote d'Ivoire er Zimbabwe Kenya er well there's going to be a greater degree of er overlap if you like between some domestic production anyway and imports from the E-U mm so if er the price of of goods fall imported from the E-U er then that's going to squeeze out er less efficient less desirable goods produced by some or er d-, domestic producers in er in the country they could only survive behind high tariff protection but you still got a lot of other production which is simply doesn't compete er with imports from the E-U that's important because this theory was developed by Viner in the context particularly of explaining er the common market all right we're going back now to the nineteen-fifties mm if you're talking about a free trade agreement a customs union i'll give you the difference between those later on er between industrialized countries in Europe between France and Germany and Italy right then the degree of substitutability between imports and domestic production is going to be very high mm so the trade creation effect on that side is potentially very powerful mm er but going to be going to be a wide range of goods which are produced for the domestic economy which you could just as well import from France or Germany or Italy mm and so er the trade creation effect would be very powerful er in an industrialized country but between an industrialized and a developing country we would expect it to be very much less but when you come to look at the empirical estimation of er the effects when you when you read the literature on on this such as it is er you will see no discussion at all or very little discussion about this particular point er nobody asked that question about er is the degree of substitutability between imports and domestic production high or low in particular what value does it have what is the elasticity of substitution absolutely no one knows mm if anybody finds a reference which tells you what that figure is even for one one developing country i'd be very grateful mm seriously grateful because part of my job is to try and measure these blasted things all right i've never found a source which is actually empirically measured the elasticity of substitution for imports from an industrialized country and domestic production everybody just assumes a number most of the of the literature on that is for industrialized countries not for developing countries and it's a very important difference the other element is the extent to which the decrease in price for the increased comsumption all right er and er that well again is an empirical fact i mean it just depends if we're talking again about very poor countries mm with very low levels of income er again the sort of comsumer goods which the E-U produces are not going to have a very big market there the the the rich elite will be able to buy their Mercedes or whatever er but er they probably buy them anyway whether the tariff was there or not and indeed because they're rich elites they're probably not paying their tariff anyway they're finding some way round it so er i don't think we need worry about that side of things what it will do however is make investment goods and intermediate goods cheaper mm than they were before mm what effect do you think that would have on the economy sm1136: nm1128: well certainly the short term effect will be a rise in imports we've just shown that sm1136: yes nm1128: okay we haven't looked at the export side of this yet that might also rise it depends what went before sm1136: nm1128: but but but but but let's but let's leave the balance of trade aside for the moment we're still quite a way from looking at that let's just look solely at the effect of doing away with the tariff and moving down the demand curve and this case the demand for investment goods and intermediate products what effect's that going to have on the economy sm1135: nm1128: sorry i'm not i i don't want to look at the export side at the moment okay i'm just looking at you know if if if investment goods and intermediate goods are cheaper what effect's it going to have sf1137: well it should somehow get an increased investment in the country nm1128: that's it that's that's what we're looking for okay so investment goods intermediate goods that you need in production all right both those factors you can buy capital goods cheaper and the costs of production are lower all right than they were before and given the height of the tariffs and non-tariff barriers okay er that er e-, existed before er that fall is going to be quite substantial er so that could be a powerful boost to investment in the economy remember one of the puzzles in many developing countries is that we have a basis for saving and investment which very often doesn't occur we can look at countries with similar income distributions and similar levels of per capita income but widely different saving and investment rates all right and we're always puzzled why and one of the reasons for that is the price of capital okay if the price of capital falls in terms of interest rates but also in terms of price of capital goods intermediate goods need in production then that could stimulate a a rise in production and just to briefly deal with your point er the balance of payments might deteriorate okay as we import these goods then production rises all right and production both of exports and of import substitutes to the extent that they exist er could then move the balance of payments the other way mm so it's a it's an empirical question sm1136: nm1128: yes i mean the-, there's a problem of financing it all that's right which we haven't discussed here we've just said imports rise the you know what you're saying to me is where does the foreign exchange come to buy it all right [laughter] and we just call that oh that's an adjustment problem you know [laughter] er but of course it's more than that you're absolutely right er so if this is going to work in a developing country and it's a very very useful point er probably with the the developing country needs aid all right er the government will need aid because its i-, its revenues have fallen quite substantially okay and it needs to change its structure of taxation from heavy dependence on import duties towards indirect taxes value added tax or something like that that's going to take time expertise et cetera right so they'll need aid and technical assistance to bridge them over that particular adjustment problem also we've got a rise in imports with nothing happening on the export side s-, in the in the short term which may be several years er that's got to be paid for or alternatively there's a balance of payments crisis currency devalued you get inflation all sorts of nasty effects could arise so again we're saying that you need financial assistance foreign exchange needs to come in in order to enable a country to buy these investment goods and er and these intermediate goods er then its production can expand er as production expands er and tradeable goods supply of tradeable goods rises so you don't need the aid that's the theory okay well we can squeeze quite a bit out of that diagram er and it is important that you understand the mechanics okay too often i think the the the textbooks simply throw that up there's A B C and D that's the consumer surplus you know blah blah blah on to the next thing on to trade diversion mm think of what's going on because if you if you think of what's going on behind the scenes here then you can say is the trade creation effect going to be large or going to be small and what are the adjustment problems for the country in terms of the government revenues and in terms of dealing with the rise in imports whenever we just said exports haven't increased any questions on that before we go on to the next one and trade diversion er happy okay right well that's the welfare gain okay er remember in this view of things the fact that you wipe out a bit of local industry er certainly means they're inefficient producers all right er which you know er shouldn't be there in the first place because they're only there under protection they go away that releases resources which can be more productively used in the rest of the economy all right that's the assumption behind it but they may just be infants that are ready to grow up sm1135: can we add nm1128: no because that's just going to effect that distance up here okay er if what you're saying is i mean i haven't actually marked that in because we got enough rubbish on this diagram that's the tariff inclusive price if there was such a price for the rest of the world in fact we're not importing from the rest of the world at all so er i'm not i'm not concerned with that no er but you're ju-, you're w-, what you're saying is that er instead of being up here the rest of the world tariff inclusive price would be up here somewhere just above that but that's irrelevant to the argument that doesn't affect the magnitude of our squares and triangles and rectangles and things underneath mm sm1135: nm1128: see sm1135: nm1128: i think what it wa-, what's con-, confusing you here is on this simple diagram er we import only from the E-U we're not importing anything from the rest of the world okay i mean i think what you're thinking in the back of your mind is in reality we import from both right er but to simplify the analysis because the E-U is the cheapest source of supply in the world we only import from the from the E-U there's no imports from the rest of the world so we don't need complicate the picture but that er i see your point yes in reality we do it okay let's look at the other side of things nm1128: okay nm1128: now er again let's go through the mechanics of this mm er whoops this thing it's difficult when it's this close to the screen can read that okay in this case it's the reverse situation to the one we had before so here the E-U is not the cheapest source of supply in the rest of the world on the contrary the tariff inclusive price P-E-U one-plus-T er is higher than the price for the rest of the world the rest of the world now is the cheapest the U-S Japan et cetera are a cheaper source of supply mm er so er at that tariff inclusive price for the rest of the world Morocco is importing M-zero mm er now that the tariff is taken away from imports from the E-U but not from the rest of the world mm the picture totally reverses okay because the rest of the world has to pay a tariff but the E-U doesn't okay we now import we switch our sources of imports from the rest of the world to the E-U the E-U now becomes the cheapest source of supply mm not because it's the most efficient but because the E-U doesn't have to pay a tariff imports from the E-U don't have to pay a tariff whereas those from the rest of the world do so we're discriminating against the rest of the world in favour of the E-U hence we switch our imports totally away from the rest of the world to the E-U even though the E-U is not the most efficient source of supply in the world right it's because either they're dearer they're less efficient less well designed but nevertheless they don't have to pay a tariff the rest of the world does and so they capture the market well that's a welfare loss mm er in its simplest terms a welfare loss because there must be something wrong with E-U goods all right otherwise we'd be importing from them in the first place right we've talked in terms of price here but remember that we've got the price and non-price characteristics of products and maybe they're just less well designed investment goods and intermediate goods they're less efficient they're not state of the art the latest technology that you get from the U-S or Japan er nevertheless you import from the E-U okay yeah the analysis is exactly the same as before er the gain in the consumer surplus is the area under the demand curve okay which is er A- plus-C okay that is that wedge in there er slightly different of course because the loss of tariff revenue is the difference between the rest of the world's price er a world prices and the tariff that's the height of the tariff sorry that's the height of the tariff in here okay so we were getting this tariff revenue from the rest of the world plus this area up in here so the tariff revenue from the rest of the world before was A-plus-B okay that's the height of the tariff multiplied by the level of imports okay well we're losing that tariff revenue er part of that loss of tariff revenue is going to who where's B going to sm1135: nm1128: in where which producers are we talking about you're right sm1135: E-U the E-U nm1128: in the E-U that's right so B is a loss of tariff revenue being handed to E-U producers okay because they are at a higher price than the price for the rest of the world okay so there's a a a transfer that's a welfare loss to Morocco it's a transfer of tariff revenue which was being previously being collected from the rest of the world now going to Philips or wherever it happens to be the immediate right er to er either boost their profits or because they are higher cost source of supply whatever it is that's a transfer to the E-U from the government of Morocco er so we've got the gain and the consumer surplus okay the area under the demand curve right we've got the loss of tariff revenue right remember that neutral so the net effect is C okay that's the so the gain and the the the net welfare effect to to Morocco in terms of the gain in consumer surplus they're paying a lower price of increased quantities of imports is C the triangle mm minus the loss of tariff revenue which has been transferred to the E-U producers okay as we've just said so the net welfare effect on Morocco is the gain and the consumer surplus right minus the loss of tariff revenue transferred to E-U producers purely as a matter of geometry if you like all right the rectangle B is going to be bigger than the triangle C mm unless unless what sm1135: nm1128: yes back to your point i think you were making earlier that's right [laugh] okay unless go on spell it out sm1135: unless the the difference er margin between the er the rest of the world and the E-U nm1128: mm sm1135: is is smaller nm1128: yes okay right so the rest of the world was just a fraction cheaper than the E-U okay then that rectangle's going to be a very small area right and so it is technically possible that that could be a very tiny rectangle compared to the triangle C in which case there would be also welfare gain but none of the textbooks say that okay er you won't find that in a textbook for the simple reason i think that it's most unlikely to occur but it's technically possible so that's trade diversion that's a welfare loss then it's a welfare loss because you're transferring government revenue from Morocco to the E-U and transferring income from Morocco to the E-U straightforwardly right it's it's like A going in the reverse direction er and secondly er we weren't buying fr-, anything from the E-U before presumably because it was a crummy source of supply okay er you know it was it was dearer it was less efficient it was yesterday's technology it was poor design nobody wanted the blasted thing okay now suddenly er you're not buying from the rest of the world you're buying only from the E-U solely solely because of the preferential trade agreement solely because the E-U no longer has to pay tariffs but the rest of the world still has to okay that's a distortion in the market it's a distortion which is welfare reducing for Morocco it it's welfare reducing for the world as a whole of course as well 'cause they there's a loss of production so at a global level there's a loss of welfare borne by whoever it was that was exporting to Morocco before U-S Japan et cetera to the other developing countries so at a global level it's a loss of welfare and it's a loss of welfare to Morocco itself i emphasized the the the impact on developing countries partly 'cause that's what we're interested in but also because again you'll read in the literature again in mostly in the development literature i have to say that you needn't worry about trade diversion 'cause that's only a global loss of welfare okay that the costs of trade diversion are borne by the rest of the world all right that's nonsense okay that's complete and utter nonsense for the reasons that we've given mm from the straightforward transfer of of government revenue to the E-U and you're buying a less efficient product than you were before mm sm1135: in this case it should be better for the devloping countries nm1128: well that that's [laughter] sm1135: nm1128: yes i mean that's what Bhagwati so so so why do you sign the wretched agreements all right [laughter] er the point i-, i mean to be a-, a-, again be impartial on this one okay because Bhagwati hates preferential trade agreements so let's be neutral about all this er there's the the the the the the static welfare effects of the preferential trade agreement are there for the net effect between the positive trade creation on the one hand and the trade diversion effect on the other okay and if trade creation our previous diagram is greater than trade diversion then Morocco gains from the preferential trade agreement okay so it's as always it's plusses and minuses okay we call swings and roundabouts er it's er there's a gain the trade creation gain the welfare gain on the one hand and the trade diversion the welfare loss on the other and it's the net effect of the two mm so the change in welfare if you like is trade creation minus trade diversion okay let's look at the magnitudes of trade diversion again our E-U Morocco agreement mm is it going to be big or small let's gask the same question as we did before and we said it's the net effect what do you think or sub-Saharan Africa sm1135: nm1128: sorry sm1135: nm1128: er is trade diversion going to be big or small when you've got an African country on the one hand and the E-U on the other what would you expect it to be same logic as we used before sm1136: nm1128: sorry sm1136: nm1128: yeah you're right sm1136: nm1128: okay give yourself time ss: nm1128: so substitutability between sm1133: nm1128: sorry sm1133: nm1128: yes okay they're the ones that are in competition with each other okay so one of the key things is what sort of goods is Morocco or Mali or Chad importing from the E-U and the rest of the world do you think there'd be same goods or different goods rough-, probably speaking sm1132: should be the same nm1128: yeah okay we s-, we said it would be investment goods and intermediate products which largely weren't produced in the domestic economy it's a bit of a simplification that but it's not wildly different from the truth okay and whether they're produced in the E-U right whether they're produced in Germany or France or Italy or Japan or er the United States or Taiwan all right or or Singapore okay it's purely a matter of price and technology and all the rest of it okay it's going to be a similar sort of mix of goods produced there so what's that going to tell you about the elasticity of substitution be precise now er between imports from the E-U and the rest of the world sm1136: nm1128: yeah it's going to be very high sm1136: very high nm1128: yeah therefore the trade diversion effect will be sm1132: high nm1128: high that's the key point okay so we would expect the magnitude of the trade diversion effect where the agreement is between an industrialized and developing country we would expect trade diversion to be large because the sort of goods you import from the E-U will be a similar sort of mix of goods to the ones that you import from other industrialized countries okay no big surprise about that so the elasticity of substitution then that's the it will will be high that's the key parameter which will determine the magnitude of the trade diversion effect mm now surprise surprise nobody's been able to measure that one either [laughter] er i'm not sure why er you can look at there's a book everybody uses by Leamer and Stern which came out in the seventies on elasticities and international trade and everybody says well they say the figure's three so i'm going to use three er and that's the figure that they've had to use you know people talk about the the elasticity of subsitution as being three for the purposes of measuring the trade diversion effect do you think that would be a a sensible figure to use that we're talking about a free trade agreement between an industrialized and developing country given what we've just said you're shaking no i mean you expect it to be what slightly more lot more sm1136: nm1128: yeah a lot more mm a lot more okay again the estimates that we work with are estimates produced for trade between industrialized countries mm which is still possibly the relevant one to use mm er but given the structure of imports er being heavily concentrated in investment goods and intermediate goods for a developing country i would imagine that the elasticity of substitution for this sort of trade agreement would be higher than the elasticity of substitution for an agreement say between Britain and France but you know we could debate about that debate about that anyway so going back to this then trade creation what conclusion did we draw about that magnitude sm1136: low nm1128: fairly low we wouldn't expect it to be very great right but the differences in levels of income in structures of production et cetera okay between the E-U and the developing country and trade diversion high so without doing any numbers at all all right simply looking at the at the determinants of trade creation and trade diversion we're going to say that trade diversion will be greater than trade creation okay in which case welfare will decline and it's going to be g-, going to take an awful lot of persuading to er tell us otherwise the only question then is how big [laughter] er you know er how big is the loss of welfare going to be okay everybody happy with the static Vinerian model yes sm1136: sign this nm1128: yes well that's [laughter] that's exactly the thing i was just going to say [laughter] i obviously led into it quite well er why do they sign it mm er why why do you sign it and really the lest of the of of the lecture and probably b-, a bit of next week going to be trying to explore why that's what economists have done ever since sm1136: nm1128: yes i mean we-, the-, the-, there's various er things we'll be through that's right where it's the sort of long runs so people say that's a static effect okay that's the once and for all effect but there's other beneficial gains to investment and blah blah blah and we'll be doing that that's right but that's the starting point okay why sign it i've given you a th-, a third diagram there which er is taken from Bhagwati 'cause i think it's a useful one er it's a variation on the er on on the model because one of the magnitudes of this er effect is going to er is going to depend also on the share of the E-U in the total imports of the developing country mm that's clearly going to be very important but haven't said anything about that we've just talked about the magnitude of the tariff change but clearly the magnitude of the trade creation effect will be larger the larger the share of the E-U in total imports of the developing country mm and conversely the trade diversion effect okay er will be er smaller the smaller the share of imports from the rest of the world other things we need in the E-U a caveat so we've implicitly i think er in our previous models assumed that the share of the E-U was quite significant that's why you're signing the agreement okay you're basically it's the developing country signing a free trade agreement with its major trading partner mm and that's the usual pattern what we're looking at here is the case where the opposite's true where the developing country is signing a free trade agreement with an industrialized country that's a minor trading partner an example would be the Caribbean countries signing a free trade agreement with the E-U okay Caribbean countries fundamentally their trade is with the U-S Canada and other Latin American countries and the E-U account for a very small proportion maybe ten per cent at most of total imports nevertheless the Caribbean is heading on the route of signing a free trade agreement with the E-U round about two-thousand-and-six two-thousand-and-eight i mean it's terribly complicated er political dynamite all round for obvious reasons the U-S are not exactly going to be jumping for joy er and [laugh] the Caribbean can't er can't really er afford to upset the U-S so not quite sure but if they want to preserve their preferential access for their exports of sugar and for bananas which are terribly important to these countries they'll have to sign a free trade agreement that's the that's the big dilemma they're faced with sm1136: nm1128: sorry the banana war again yes no yes there'll be another one [laughter] so this is an agreement then between er the Caribbean countries and the E-U with the E-U counting a maybe only a small proportion of imports well as i put here er it's a question of price-takers and price-makers all right that we talked about last term er here fundamentally prices are set by the U-S okay that's the big source of supply okay and E-U producers simply er sell er in in the market at the price set by the U-S suppliers okay they have they're such a small proportion of the market that they have no influence on price okay common sense assumption okay let me see what what happens in this case well again we've got free er w-, er er free trade imports from er the E-U er here and imports from the rest of the world call that United States okay but the difference in this case is that because the U-S is the major source of supply it's the price-maker perfectly elastic supply okay the Caribbean however is a distant market er for E-U producers substantial transport costs only a small proportion of their export's going there so transport costs would be a significant proportion of total cost so the supply curve will be anything but perfectly elastic er it'll be fairly steep re-, reflecting the fact that they command only a small proportion of the market price is set here so the U-S sets the price in the Caribbean market the E-U suppliers provide m-, move up their supply curve until they hit point B okay and er at that point which is set by the U-S er price plus the tariff okay er then that determines imports from the E-U O-Q-one okay and then the rest of imports come from the U-S now let's take the tariff away from er imports from the E-U but not from the U-S okay free trade agreement with E-U mm er in that case then we show the effect of that by an output movement of the E- U supply curve okay er in which case imports from the E-U expand from Q-one out to Q-two okay the important thing to note is that nothing happens to the internal price levels in the Caribbean 'cause they're set by U-S suppliers so it's U-S supply plus the tariff so it's the tariff inclusive U-S price which sets the domestic price level in the Caribbean mm what the E-U exporters do is simply maximize profits with price is set by the U-S suppliers so imports from the U-S expand from Q-one out to Q-two mm er there's a loss of tariff revenue to the Caribbean governments of A- C- G-E okay that area in there where they previously collected the tariff now that's being lost and guess who's getting it su1138: nm1128: no the E-U okay that got to be the U-S are still paying the tariffs excuse me er the but but the E-U suppliers aren't paying the tariff mm nothing's happened to the domestic price level 'cause they're price-takers okay so that loss of tariff revenue goes straight into the pockets of the E-U exporters very nicely thank you mm er and that's it there is no gain for the consumers because nothing happens to the price er the internal price level of the Caribbean doesn't fall because the E-U er previously was accounting for maybe ten per cent of imports now goes up to fifteen per cent of imports but it's not going to affect price okay you still get eighty-five per cent of of imports coming from the U-S that's what determines the internal price level in the Caribbean so the price-makers of the U-S exporters the E-U exporters are price-takers mm they can't influence price they're too small to do so so they simply clean up in terms of the of not having having to pay the tariff they previously had to they simply boost their profits er no gain in consumer surplus straightforward deterioration in the terms of trade from the Caribbean against the E-U er straightforward transfer of government revenue from the Caribbean governments and people to the E-U producers full stop end of story that's the price of continuing to get access for your exports of sugar and bananas and you can measure it [laughter] get to make the right assumptions when i i actually went through this one when we because er as you know there's er all the er will be up to about two-thousand-and-six two-thousand-and-eight the trade negotiations er going on er with the commission er over there that will be starting quite soon and i went through that analysis er with the and the with people over the the within the the commission er there was a [laughter] it wasn't favourably received [laughter] er people were unhappy with the idea that the price wouldn't change er but that's the reality i mean it's an empirical question okay but if you account for only ten or fifteen per cent of the market and the Caribbean group very helpfully told me well actually that was a bit high it's about seven or eight per cent actually you know in many countries then you're a price-taker you don't influence price and that's what the whole analysis hinges on er so that's er by way of er a variation of a theme yeah sm1132: one question the role of the U-S company in that last model nm1128: yes is to get very upset you know sm1132: as a price-ma as a price-maker i mean how i mean how how will the U-S respond nm1128: well they get very upset [laughter] yes i mean er it's obviously it's it's crowding out er imports from the U-S that's right yeah that's it sm1132: so is there anything the U the U-S will do in that situation nm1128: yes i mean that's the that's the big issue that's the dilemma which the Caribbean countries are faced with sm1132: how nm1128: because at the at the currently they have er under the Caribbean Basin Initiative they have preferential access to the U-S market principally for clothing i mean that's the key one for them really er you know i can't imagine the U-S standing by and continuing to allow them that preferential access while their exporters are saying but we're losing market share sm1132: so isn't the isn't rea-, to the er Caribbean countries in this example are better off sticking with the price-maker than rather nm1128: and but then if they don't sign the free trade agreement they lose their exports of sugar and and bananas and that cause large scale unemployment in Jamaica and in the er you know the er er Windward Islands sm1132: but then again if if if that happens then the U-S might retaliate say well you know nm1128: yeah sm1132: to import from nm1128: yeah sm1132: Indonesia or somewhere else nm1128: and then the so so the guys in the in the in in the sugar and banana plantations do all right but the guys in the clothing industry are unemployed sm1136: nm1128: [laughter] yeah that's the dilemma they've got sm1136: nm1128: right sm1136: nm1128: yeah sm1136: nm1128: mm sm1136: nm1128: well that is well th-, yes that is exactly what the Caribbean and and and CARICOM in particular the Caribbean community which is a free trade agreement in fact it's it's moving over to a customs union there and they're physically signing i mean some of those hundred-and-six agreements i mentioned were between CARICOM er and various Latin American countries 'cause they see that as being their future sm1136: nm1128: yes sm1136: nm1128: yeah yeah that's right that's right so er better off building up your trade with Latin America yes i mean i a-, again it's an example of of the patterns of trade not being determined so much by purely economic considerations as by a colonial heritage er that's why their export in sugar and bananas to Europe er in a free trade situation they may or may not be doing so probably wouldn't er free trade probably sugar will be coming from India or from Brazil or somewhere like that where a a very low cost producer well it's from Australia are a very low cost producer not from the Caribbean i mean that's a reflection of the fact that were British colonies er i'm not saying that market er but and that's created a dilemma and similarly with clothing you see the clothing industry in Jamaica which is a quite an important source of employment for them that live there is principally because of the Caribbean Basin Initiative it's because of preferences in the U-S market without those preferences again in a free trade situation the clothing would come from Asia not from Jamaica i mean Jamaica then says well what the heck are we going to produce but but you've got the answer i mean the answer is that it'll be other things which of course we don't know about because they don't exist but er the obvious trade pattern would be towards Latin American countries that have a different resource base a different level of income a different stage of technology so the two economies are complementary to each other and that's the future for these countries' problems but that gets us away from here anyway that's just er a variation on the on the i mean th-, th-, the the previous models assume that the partner country in the trade agreement was a price-maker okay this is a case where the partner country's a price-taker with the rest of the world determining the price and that alters the analysis okay so why sign the damn thing [laughter] you know [laughter] er and that's er as i say that's the question which everybody has er you know really teased their brains about er you have to look to the so-called dynamic arguments okay i don't like the term dynamic because we've nicked it off thermodynamics or physics or something like that er growth enhancing i think is more accurate okay er phrase so it's a growth enhancing effects of a free trade agreement what might they be 'cause remember trade creation and trade diversion are once and for all static effects okay they just have a once and for all impact and that's it okay fundamentally what we're talking about here is accelerating the growth of these countries okay it's a continuous process so okay trade diversion might be greater than trade creation all right but that's just a once and for all cost if you like mm er is there something about the free trade agreements that has a continuous effect on increasing output year by year more rapidly than would otherwise have occurred if you hadn't signed the free trade agreement and those who favour free trade agreements say those are the really important things those growth enhancing effects they're the really important ones but they're difficult to measure rather fortunate that perhaps but er the other ones are difficult to measure anyway so the first one then obvious one is er economies of scale okay basically the argument is a simple one er the developing country has access to a wider market so previously if you imagine producers simply selling in the home market the home market's small 'cause you're a small country small size of population and you've got a low level of per capita G-N-P so er the effect of that is er er to mean that if that's the long run average cost curve er then you know it you're probably this is cost output your small size of the domestic market producing a P-A just producing er a production for the for the for the home market er means that you're operating at quite high average cost of production you then sign a free trade agreement gives you access to this huge E-U market i don't know how many million people there are i've forgotten how many there are in the E-U sm1132: two-hundred-and-forty something like that nm1128: right sm1136: three-hundred-and nm1128: yeah sm1136: nm1128: yeah three-hundred-and-fifty-million people okay and instead of your population of twelve-million [laughter] er so you don't need too many of that three-hundred-and-fifty-million people to buy your goods to be able to move somewhere out here okay er so you may er having free access unrestricted access to this huge market enables you to increase exports expand productions way above the constraint of the er domestic market and you move down your long run average cost curve okay and that makes you even more competitive of course than you were before and so exports expand even more so you get a a virtuous process if you're moving down if you expand your exports you're moving down the long run average cost curve because you're more efficient than you were before producing a lower average cost than before you sell more output and so you go on moving down the average cost curves in that way sm1132: i'm sorry just er one point is the assumption here that er we have free er trade agreement just between the developing countries and for example the E- U er but what what if we say well got er free trade nm1128: mm sm1132: you know w-, with the whole world then obviously do we have still economies of scale then that is the question nm1128: well then it gets complicated for the reasons that you've indicated because everybody else has got a free trade agreement all right er so you've just got free trade i mean ultimately then you've just got world free trade in which case comparative advantage should work on a on a world basis all right and provided you've got a comparative advantage in this product the same argument should hold mm i mean the only difference is that this might hold for a product in which you don't have a comparative advantage on a worldwide level all right but you do in terms of trade with E-U so if you just had a an agreement between Morocco and E-U nothing else in the world all right Morocco can move down its long run average cost curve say for clothing it's an important industry in Morocco okay mm er because it doesn't have to compete with Asia and the rest but if the E-U signs agreements up with all the Asian countries and Eastern Europe and everybody else okay then that might not hold you had to have a comparative advantage at a world level so er i mean in a sense you see what what i'm saying is that er a preferential trade agreement can create a false comparative advantage mm because you have free access to the E-U but the rest of the world doesn't okay then you're more competitive but it's a false comparative advantage mm and as more agreements are signed you might well find that you've committed yourself to produce clothing but then you're left high and dry because you're a high cost producer just that the Caribbean countries er had a false comparative advantage in selling bananas in the U-K market or sugar cane in the U-K market only because they have preferential access to to to Britain but Australia Brazil er Ecuador in the case of bananas and so on er didn't mm so it created a false comparative adavantage they built up these industries and now when we've got free trade virtually on those products er they can't survive without preferences sm1132: so basically as the for example the European Union er signs more and more trade agreements nm1128: yes sm1132: which it's which is in the process of doing so now nm1128: yes that's right sm1132: with the Caribbean with Eastern Europe and other countries er nm1128: that's right sm1132: and so so basically that preferential er lose nm1128: margin sm1132: er it loses it's er significance nm1128: absolutely absolutely that's right that's right er yes i mean it's er yes i mean it whi-, which of course er those who say therefore free trade agreements are stepping stones to multilateral trade liberalization might exa-, you know say well that's exactly what i'm saying mm that they're just stepping stones to world free trade i shall point out at the end it's not quite as simple as that 'cause the agreements differ in their content and that creates barriers to trade but that's getting a-, that's jumping the gun a bit but that's right we're talking as if it was the only agreement in the world mm er obviously if it isn't then that that reduces the gains to Morocco or wherever it happens to be but then we move over more to just global or multilateral trade liberalization getting closer to that perhaps okay so the first dynamic gain might be economies of scale you move down your long run average cost curve the second one the familiar one to us from any trade liberalization er greater competition mm to the extent that imports compete with domestic production we're back to that argument again the elasticity of substitution between domestic production and imports if that's small then that argument's not terribly important er but it's still going to e-, exist a wider choice of goods okay previously you'd all sorts of barriers to trade i mean many developing countries in the past anyway simply prohibited a whole range of imported goods so as to conserve foreign exchange for so-called essentials mm er free trade widens choice that's a a welfare gain in itself increase in foreign direct investment people particularly emphasize this gain here and er the two terms here investment creation and investment deflection er investment creation somebody tell me about that sm1135: er it's like sm1135: the share of the market nm1128: right okay so we've got two forces working just like the trade aspect okay first of all let's again go back to our agreement between E-U and Morocco mm now er er previously we had barriers to trade between the two countries er let let's assume that was the case er now we've a situation where there's no barriers to trade at all a producer of say clothing in France where labour costs are high mm can now close down that factory relocate it in Morocco where labour costs are much lower er and then export er the output back into France again so that the er the manufact-, the the the clothing manufacturer can now serve the domestic market in France much more cheaply than they could before er as a result of the preferential trade agreement mm so er that's one gain from the free trade agreement yeah sm1135: so the [cough] there would be in er inves-, investment diversion from the nm1128: in the sense of sm1135: in the sense of maybe er an investor will move er and then the export nm1128: yes that was the case i was i was i was going though just now sm1136: nm1128: well it's i-, er er it's normally called in-, in-, investment deflection that one sm1136: nm1128: okay er but it's it's a bit i mean it depends which as you say which wh- , which standpoint you view it from er but if you're viewing it from the E-U point of view it's investment deflection okay er in the case of the er say the United States okay that was previously selling goods in the you know that that was exporting goods to Morocco mm but now a trade diversion against it okay it may wish to retain its market share in Morocco okay in which case it replaces its exports by investment in a plant which will produce the goods previously exported and that's called investment creation right it's called i-, it's the creation of investment because investment is taking the place of exports as a way of servicing the market so yeah sf1137: nm1128: yes previously i mean let's say they were selling say agricultural machinery to Morocco and they were exporting that from the U-S to Morocco now because of o-, of trade diversion the-, the-, they they've lost the market the market was big enough then they might say we want to retain our market share by jumping the tariff wall in in Morocco if there's still place for it and setting up an assembly plant for the combine harvesters the tractors in in Morocco and in s-, and and and and continuing to retain its market share sf1137: nm1128: right sf1137: nm1128: i-, i-, i-, investment deflection yeah sf1137: invest deflection nm1128: yeah investment deflection is France er closing down a factory in France and setting up a clothing factory in Morocco it's deflecting investment from investment in the home country to investment in in Morocco sf1137: other word for deflection nm1128: these are the technical terms that are used in the literature sm1135: de-investment nm1128: sorry sm1135: de-investment nm1128: yes i mean i-, it's ca-, it's called deflection because it's simply in-, in-, investment taking place in a different geographical location mm but the total amount of investment hasn't increased all right it's just been deflected to a different geographical location hence the word deflection [laughter] not a not that i mean if you can imagine sort of investment flowing in into France over the years then the preferential trade agreement's signed and it's closed off there and it's deflected off down towards Morocco okay that's whereas the other case is creation of investment that didn't exist before okay you're not closing anything down in the United States necessarily i mean they'll probably sell the factory somewhere else what you're doing is in-, instead of servicing the market through exports you now service it through investment in a production facility so it's i-, it's creation of investment that didn't exist before sf1137: but it is the U-S would have to look what to do with nm1128: yes but we don't ask that question that's right [laughter] 'cause that's the rest of the world and the rest of the world's very big all right er and Morocco's very small so we needn't bother about that question that's all we're saying so er whoops the the the first case er we-, well i mentioned here anyway the the the investment deflection can be quite important i i didn't pick clothing by accident er 'cause it's the one in which you very often see this er where er particularly the the labour intensive stages of the production process could often be relocated from the industrialized country to the developing country that's what the U-S is doing in Jamaica talked about the Caribbean Basin Initiative agreement er this is what France indeed has done in Morocco all right and that is what Egypt is hoping will happen er if it signs a free trade agreement er with the E-U that there'll be this outward processing er will take place on quite a large scale whether that's beneficial or not for the country is another question we talked about that under on direct investment but that would be a clear case of investment deflection mm investment creation would be the U-S coming in to Egypt because they er they're they're losing their market and it's a big market for the U-S yeah sm1132: just one question say you're a policy maker in Morocco or in the Caribbean and er you've done your analysis you've looked at the gains you have and of free trade agreements well i've got on one side er er trade creation the other hand i've got trade diversion but i also have dynamic er dynamic gains along with that nm1128: right sm1132: er i mean you have nothing to measure you have [laughter] nm1128: no that's right sm1132: you know how do you how do you decide this case and it's very difficult nm1128: yeah sm1132: it's a very difficult choice nm1128: er sm1132: to make nm1128: yeah i mean you just have to in the end you have to trust your judgement er all you can do however is analyse the situation okay and what this does is provide you with a framework of saying are these things going to be important okay let's go back to the Morocco case all right er Morocco actually had already had preferences with the E-U okay so at the stimulating an effects on its exports were zero okay because they already had preferential access under a bilateral agreement so Morocco could say forget that economies of scale okay because we've we we reaped those in the past all right er er and we're not being given any more preferences greater competition er well the goods that we import from E-U compete to a limited extent with domestic production but not a lot so that's not going to be great wider choice of goods similar sort of argument er maybe a little bit more than we did before because we had but we're already dismantling barriers to trade anyway you know er so that's not going to be great increased foreign direct investment er well what's changed you know er the only thing that's changed that may be important is that my tariffs on importing goods setting up a production facility in Morocco er the er er i-, i-, er it's certainly i-, it's more profitable to set up a production facility in Morocco than it was before if a French er clothing manufacturer was setting up a factory in Morocco all the machinery and the intermediate goods would have to pay duty previously er but er they they no longer have to do so er but the duties usually are not terribly high on these products in developing countries it's consumer goods that carry the very high tariffs i mean it may be tariffs of you know ten per cent or so so it might make a difference er but not a a dramatic amount and am i going to get investment from the rest of the world i'm a tiny little market right if this is Brazil that's signing an agreement okay then sure i mean as soon as as er as the Mercasor agreement was signed American investment poured in er to retain market share very big market Brazil er b-, t-, er er er er Morocco what's its population did we say sm1133: nm1128: sorry sm1133: nm1128: is it as much as that sm1132: i don't think it's that much sm1133: sm1132: it's even less than that nm1128: mm yes it's pretty small sm1133: nm1128: and and Tunisia's what about twelve-million sm1135: nm1128: yeah yeah yeah so we've we've got a small er a small market so thi-, this is the way you'd go through it yeah sm1135: nm1128: right sm1135: nm1128: yes if you sm1135: nm1128: mm sm1135: the er access to er Moroccan or Egyptian market nm1128: mm sm1135: nm1128: that's right so y-, but you you have to i mean going through the point y-, y-, d-, you already had preferential access before so you ask the question how much has it increased all right sm1135: yeah potential nm1128: yeah now one key thing though is that you you may have had preferences before but they were unilateral preferences a free trade agreement is a a binding agreement mm a legally binding agreement of indefinite duration and that might give the investors greater confidence than they had under the previous thing so that might be a big plus and these are the questions i mean what this does is provide a framework for asking a whole series of questions that's i can forget about that one that's not going to be terribly big that's going to be small this one might be big it might not we have to look at that more carefully and that's what it does and then at the end of the day you make a judgement but the big question too is all of these things i've mentioned here you could get from unilateral trade liberalization at least a lot of it anyway mm er i mean you wouldn't nes-, i mean you wouldn't get the so much the investment creation investment deflection effects that wouldn't tell us very much but the other ones economies of scale greater competition wider choice of goods er we'd all i would all get if i simply lowered my barriers to trade with the world as a whole and there'd be no trade diversion cost mm so again we come back and think why the hell did we sign the agreement right er okay there might be this er investment creation investment deflection effects to the extent that they're important er as i say i would think fundamentally that depends how big an economy you are mm if you're a small economy i wouldn't expect it to be terribly great may be wrong er Mauritius might be an example where it was quite substantial mm er where you know it's it's the third largest exporter of woollen clothes in the world and it's a tiny little island and that's largely because of preferences so yeah we got to be careful with that one i-, i-, it could be important er but er so so maybe that's important but in terms of stimulating foreign direct investment because duties on imports of capital goods and intermediate goods have come down well liberalize to the world as a whole mm so investors can then buy capital goods and intermediate goods at world prices mm not simply er at whatever price the E-U exporter sells them to you so we still got really we still haven't really answered the question why sign the agreement we've got the gains from trade but why not just get those on a non-discriminatory basis through unilateral trade liberalization why do it in a in a discriminatory way we've still got that puzzle well er next week i'll go through some new thinking and er to explain why some of the what those gains might be i've hinted at one of them already that is in an uncertain world binding yourself in to a free trade agreement provides you with a bit more certainty so if i engage in unilateral trade liberalization and it's or maybe with other countries er negotiate reciprocal tariff reductions in the W-T- O er there's always the danger of going back to the nineteen-thirties all right there's always the W-T-O has been weakened by the Seattle er situation that we've talked about before okay maybe it's not quite such a strong organization that we thought it was okay maybe if there was serious unemployment in the industrialized countries the whole agreement would just be torn up and we'd be back to the er er discrimination and er barriers to trade of the nineteen-thirties you know that's not improbable but if i lock myself in to the E-U or to United States through a free trade agreement maybe that gives me a bit more certainty okay it's a i-, it's a it's a legally binding agreement you'd build up institutional arrangements which link you in with the other country so when push comes to shove all right if we if we did have a bit of a recession in the u-, in the E-U or or United States they'll discriminate against other people er not against me at least not in the first instance all right so bit more certainty then perhaps yeah sm1132: nm1128: well it yeah i mean in the case of Eastern European agreements it's heavily political all right you're trying to reinforce the overthrow of communism er democratic governments as long as they're not communist governments er and so on that's right so i mean that was a heavy political element in that one that was the top of the of the agenda and the E-U was willing to pay quite a high price to maintain that with the other dev-, o-, other developing countries not really willing to pay a price and that in a sense is part of the of of also of the puzzle the developing countries in effect i mean from what we've said have to pay quite a high price upfront right at the beginning for these agreements okay that's the welfare loss there's the rising unemployment as industries close down that are competing with imports from the E-U there's the loss of government revenue you know there's a lot of upfront costs for the developing country from the agreement really not much cost for the industrialized country mm so why do they sign why do developing countries sign these agreements with industrialized countries hinted at one of them and that's that's increased certainty i think that figures quite prominently but there's other aspects as well that we'll talk about next week to do with timing consistency problems signalling all sorts of other things that we talk about any final points okay well i'll carry on doing the theory and then we'll talk a bit more about actual agreements next week and then we'll get on to talk about article twenty-four and er how it i-, its weaknesses and how it needs to be reformed hopefully in a Seattle type row whatever it's going to be called [laugh] thank you