nm0757: er two three weeks is to er is to try and build up a framework a a model that will allow us to understand how consumers make choices and we've almost got to the end of the er what people would like to buy element er of the framework and then what we're going to try and do today when we've finished that off is to actually put it together to try and er create a framework a model that will allow us to understand the choices that actually made so we going to put together that availability set the things that people can choose and the part that looks at what they actually want to choose to actually look at the choices that are actually made and what we want to try and do is to put that framework together in such a way that we can use it not just in an academic sense to have some nice diagrams but to actually predict what people will choose er and to look at what happens when things change so if we can build this framework up we can try and understand well if prices change what's going to happen to the demand for a good is it going to go up is it going to go down and by how much likew-, wise with income for example if income changes how will demand change er and by how much so that's where we want to to end up now if you remember where we got to er at the end of last week was we we started at the end of last week hang on try and remember which of these light switches it is again where we have all of this this space these combinations of two goods X-one and X-two okay and if you remember we said well we can represent it in two dimensions but really we're looking at the choices between all the goods and services that consumers have available to them and we started saying well what the consumer can do we assume is compare any combination of these goods wherever it is and can say i prefer this point that combination of the two goods over this point and so on and that they can compare all the possible combinations of the things that are available to them okay and say i prefer this combination to that combination and they do that er they have these preferences they can say that they have strong preference i prefer A over B i'm indifferent i don't care which i have or weak preference i prefer A to B or i'm indifferent between the two and then what we we did was we said okay that's fine but what we want to try and do is to build up the model that will allow us to predict choices and to do that we have to make certain assumptions about the preferences that consumers have and we we had all these assumptions of completeness there are no black holes there are no er combinations of the goods that the consumer can't express a preference over transitivity that is that we have this rule that if you say i prefer A to B and i prefer B to C we can assume that they prefer A over C and we've we we said that often that doesn't hold but er at least logically it seems that a rational consumer might have transitive preferences we then had the idea of reflexivity that if a if a consumer couldn't compare a good or combination of goods to any other they could compare them to themselves and using that okay we said okay every single one of these points er we can express a preference over but there won't be any inconsistencies we then went on to say okay can we make any general rules about the direction of the consumer's preference and we had the idea of non-satiation which means that preferences go out in that direction I-E that within the realms of most of the choices that consumers make with lots and lots of goods and services available to them they will prefer more to less they prefer more of the goods to less of the goods and if that is the case their preferences will go out in that direction and hence we automatically can say for example that this point here is preferred to that point there simply because it has more of er both of er the goods er and therefore automatically the consumer will prefer more we then said okay if that's the case then we can start talking about indifference lines and because that is the case an indifference line or indifference curve must have a negative slope okay that is if we combi-, if we we draw a line that combines all of the combinations of these goods between which the consumer is indifferent it must be the case that if you get more of one good you have less of another and w-, the measure of that is the marginal rate of substitution okay the slope of the line so that's negative and it's a measure of the trade off between these two goods which reflects the relative preference that the consumer has for one good over another so if a consumer really likes X-one if they give up one unit of X-one they're going to require a lot of X-two to take its place okay for example then we said okay that's fine but looking at the way c-, they're looking at the sorts of preferences that consumers have what we tend to find is that this rate of trade off this marginal rate of substitution isn't constant okay and we said in fact that we would expect the indifference curve to be convex to the origin which means that the rate of trade off at this point here when you have a lot of X-two and not much X-one will be different to the rate of trade off here where you have a lot of X-one and not much X-two because we know that as you get more of a good its marginal utility declines and and vice versa so where we ended up last time was with basically the ability to represent sort of colour to represent the consumer's preferences between these two goods okay as a series of indifference curves like this that are negatively sloped convex to the origin the direction of the consumer's preferences is out here so we automatically know that indifference curve two is preferred to indifference curve one every single combination of the two goods on this indifference curve des-, is preferred to every single combination on indifference curve one and likewise indifference curve three every combination on that indifference curve is preferred to indifference curve two okay and so on so the least preferred point is this point here zero consumption 'cause the consumer gets no utility because they only get utility from consumption from the goods and the maximum is some infinite point up here okay er whoo-, whoops where they consume however much because at the moment they have no constraints okay because we haven't brought the availability set in er so this is what they would like to do okay now you may say okay that's totally unrealistic because eventually the consumer will grow satiated okay now that may be true with er two goods but remember if we try and represent this with all the goods available then we can have very small substitutions between all the different goods that are available and we would assume that normally within the realms of of balanced consumption of consuming a large number of different goods that the consumer will operate within the context of not having great satiation in most circumstances okay so that's where where we got to and that's fine we can so far wh-, if i could draw it do it in three dimensions we could do three goods okay but that is just a diagram it is it's just a representation a a theoretical model of er the consumer's preferences we can't use it at the moment to do anything except er to to try and think about the way in which choices are made what we need to do is to be able to represent this numerically we need to be able to represent these indifference curves in a numerical form 'cause if we can do that if you remember the availability set can be represented er er mathematically because you have the budget line what we need to be able to do is to represent these algebraically mathematically er and then we can combine the two together and use that to actually predict the ch-, the co-, the choices the consumer would actually make if we can al-, also if we can represent it algebraically of course we're not constrained to three goods which is what we are in a three-dimensional diagram we can have however many goods that the consumer has available to them okay so we need to represent this in some other way and so the final assumption is that we can represent these indifference curves algebraically and that they are differentiable okay that is that if we we we can differentiate them so that we can derive an optimum okay we can derive a point er a choice that the consumer will make when we put all of all all of the information together the two sides so that's the final assumption that that we are we are going to make now we're not going to go into er a lot of the m-, of the mathematics okay it's it's the basic principle that really matters here okay now the complication we have is that we have said that utility is not measurable in a cardinal sense that is we cannot say for example that if a consumer er has a certain consumes a certain combination of goods their utility is level X and then if they consume another combination it's level Y okay we can't say there's a l-, level utility ten and another combination of goods gives you level of utility twenty we've said we can't do that we can't measure utility er and even if we could we couldn't combine it across individuals because it's totally individual er to that consumer that seems to fly in the face of saying well we want to represent those indifference curves mathematically algebraically and we want to be able to predict the choice they make that's because the reason for that conflict is that all of the mathematical functions that you will have seen to date are what called a-, are are are called cardinal functions that is functions where the numbers are measuring things so if we have a value of ten we can say that is half of a value of twenty okay now what we are going to do is to use a type of function that is called an ordinal function and an ordinal function is a function where the numbers only matter in terms of their relative position so if you have values of one and two the two is greater than one okay it doesn't matter how much but it's just greater okay so that all that matters in an ordinal function is order not relative position okay so what we want to do is we have our indifference curves like this and we want to be able to represent those indifference curves with a number okay algebraically and presume that we can represent that utility function as er U-X- one-X-two that is utility the satisfaction they get is a function of the amounts of these goods which is what we've said and don't get they don't get satisfaction from anything else they just get it from consumption in in the context of the market and clearly the amount of the utility depends on the quantities of those two goods and that's exactly what this diagram says okay it says that er [cough] if we have this combination and this combination these two points here the level of utility's exactly the same although the quantities of these two goods is actually different because the consumer is indifferent between those two combinations and we've said that if we have a combination here the the level of utility is greater again the quantities of the two goods are different but the level of utility that the consumer gets is is greater because it's on a higher indifference curve and so what we want to do is to represent these these indifference curves [cough] as what is called a utility function a function that simply says the utility the consumer gets is a function mathematically of the quantity of X-one and the quantity of X-two okay the quantity the amount of the two goods one of these could be zero [cough] so if the consumer got no utility at all from the consumption of that good then simply the the expression relating to say X-one this good here would just be zero okay so that's possible er and if the consumer go-, got no utility at all from these two then it would be zero for both okay so we can represent that no no problem at all but we don't we're not going to represent these indifference curves with a function which assumes that we're measuring utility so we're going to use er what is termed a a an ordinal function [cough] okay so we're not going back to a world where yeah we can measure marginal utility et cetera we're still in a world of of indifference curves okay that's so that's that's fine okay [cough] the type of function we want is as is as follows if we assume that we have two consumption bundles X-one er and X-two okay and these are the utility functions that represent those two consumption bundles so X- one here is a combination of these two goods and X-two here is a combination of these two goods a different combination [cough] and what we want to do is to effectively so U-X-one okay could be associated with this indifference curve here and U-X-two could be associated with this indifference curve here okay for example what we want is to put numbers on these things so hence any combination of goods that lay on indifference curve two would have a greater number than any combination on indifference curve one okay now let's assume that we give we have a lar-, a larger value for U-X-one this combination than U-X-two what that would mean of course is that the consumer preferred this combination to that combination that is that X-one was preferred to X-two okay and that's what that would imply is that the consumer strictly preferred X-one over X-two the other possible scenario is that U -X-one is equal to U -X-two like if two goods were on the same indifference curve and that would assume that the consumer was indifferent okay so we want to represent these indifference curves in such a way that either if the consumer is indifferent the value we give the number we give is exactly the same okay if the consumer prefers one bundle of goods over another we will give a bigger number to the er bundle the consumer prefers what th-, th-, the the very important thing to get clear in your mind is it doesn't matter what the number is okay all that matters is that we give the same number to bundles of goods between which the consumer is indifferent and we give a bigger number to combinations of goods that the consumer prefers it doesn't matter how much bigger okay and that is the crucial difference if it mattered how much bigger the number was we would be using it as a real measure of utility we'd be saying that if it was a value of ten that would be half a value of twenty all we're saying is that if we give a value of ten that is less than twenty doesn't matter how much because we're not measuring utility we're just measuring order hence it is called an ordinal function okay so any combinations on one indifference curve will have the same number any higher indifference curve any combinations that are on a higher diss-, indifference curve will have a bigger number it doesn't matter how much bigger the number is okay so let's assume for example that we have er three no sorry four er consumption bundles okay these are four different combinations of those goods and we have a utility function U-X okay now if we assume that X-one that that this combination X-one and this combination X-two the consumer is totally indifferent between them they will have exactly the same number say five and five okay and let's assume that they prefer X-three over those two and it may then have a number of ten and they like X-four even more and that could have a number which is say twenty okay so X-one and X-two are indifferent they pref-, thi-, this consumer prefers X-three over two and one and prefers four over three two and one let's assume that we have let's think say another function that we rec-, we could we and we give another numerical representation to er to this consumer's preferences and let's say we have a value of er a thousand here again the numbers are the same hence the consumer's indifferent let's assume the number given to X-three is ten-thousand that indicates the consumer prefers X-three over two and one it does not say that they prefer the consu-, X-two more than when we had a value of ten okay all that matters is that that number is bigger than the numbers given to X-one and X-two it doesn't matter how much because we're not measuring utility all that matters is relative er positioning and so we could have a value of say a million given to X-four and again that doesn't tell us anything more than the values here it's exactly the same because all that matters is relative ordering hence it's an ordinal function the higher the number the greater the consumer's preference okay that's true but it doesn't say how much higher it is it just says it is higher so whenever a number is bigger than another number it means the consumer has greater preference they will go for that combination of goods rather than one to which we've allocated a lower number how much the number differs is irrelevant it could differ by you know one decimal point or it could differ by a million the information is exactly the same because what we're well what we're not saying is that this how the consumer chooses you know they they think in their head what is my utility function how much utility do i get from these combinations what we're saying is that we want to represent er these these ideas that we have about their preferences in a numerical way okay we don't want to measure utility because we assumed that we can't do that but what we do want to do is to say we want to give a bigger number to a higher indifference curve because of course what we want to do is to produce a model that says the consumer aims for the highest indifference curve okay they aim for the one which is furthest up okay we're not saying that we can measure their utility we're saying is that all they will do is to strive for the highest indifference curve okay and that is er that is all these are termed ordinal functions and they are very different to the sorts of functions that you see we can treat them in exactly the same way as any other mathematical function we can do everything to them that we can do to another mathematical function the only difference is the interpretation we give to these numbers all that matters is their relative position okay how much they are different does not matter simply because er we're not measuring their utility we're just measuring order okay do you do you understand that distinction between the two types of functions and and what those functions are representing yeah simply they're saying if we get more preference we have a bigger number doesn't matter how much that's irrelevant okay and it does take you know given you've been used to using other the other functions in in other ways it does take some sort of getting your head round but er okay that's th-, basically what what we want to do once we once we've said we can do that we can give a number to the preferences then we just have to decide what is the mathematical form okay what is the mathematical form and i'm just going to quickly give you some er examples [cough] okay er some some extreme examples okay th-, the normal case that we'd tend to find and then just some extreme examples so that you er you understand [cough] now you've been used to seeing er indifference curves like this okay fine they represent the sorts of things th-, the sort of assumptions that we've built up the sort of assumptions we built up last week and which is a convex marginal rate of substitution changes as the combinations of the good change tha-, tha-, it's negative okay so there's a trade off between the goods the consumer prefers a higher indifference curve to a lower one and so on okay if they're the assumptions we make then we want to be able to represent those types of preferences between the goods in some mathematical form and the normal form that is used there okay is er is a quadratic form of some kind okay that simply says that er and these here are your marginal rates of substitution alpha and beta okay so these are the marginal utilities of the goods the ratio of those will be the marginal rate of substitution okay so alpha is the marginal utility associated with X-one er and beta is the marginal rate of substitution associated with X-two and of course the ratio of those which is the slope of the indifference curve will give you the marginal rate of substitution okay and all we've said is okay this mathematical function okay will dem-, will will display mathematical properties like we have here okay I-E that represents that will allow us algebraically to represent that okay the alpha marginal utility of of X-one -beta marginal utility of X- two the ratio between alpha and beta marginal rate of substitution which is a piece of information we may want and directly we can represent this algebraically we can get that marginal rate of substitution okay of course it may change according to which point on the indifference curve we are because we've said that's what happens so it will change according to the absolute amounts of X-one and X-two okay er but that would represent that and so that is the normal form that is used okay okay it's a bit er more difficult er mathematically to deal with because it's not linear but in fact if you take the logs of that it becomes linear anyway so so it's relatively easy to use but that is the sort of thing that we might use to represent the normal types of preferences that we assume consumers have okay so that's one form that we might use and then what we would do okay is X-one and X- two will be the quantities of the goods and of course if there are ten goods there will be ten of these X-one X-two X-three up to X-ten and there'll be ten of these marginal utilities okay and then again there will be a marginal rate of substitution between all of the pairs of goods that the consumer has available to them so X-one and X-two there'll be a marginal rate of substitution between X -one and X-three and so on okay and that will simply be these ratios the ratios between these but all we're saying is that that mathematical form can represent that we're not saying that the consumer goes in the shop and gets out a calculator with that sort of mathematical function imprinted in it we're saying that that is a mathematical way of representing the preferences that we've said the consumer might have the model that we've we've actually built up okay [cough] an alternative form might be as follows these are linear indifference curves straight lines okay they're different to the previous ones because the other ones are convex they're curved these ones are straight lines how much or to what extent does the marginal rate of substitution change as you go up and down on the indifference curve like this go up go down sm0758: constant sf0759: constant nm0757: it's constant yeah so the marginal rate of substitution doesn't change it's constant okay it's still going to be that ratio al-, A alpha over beta okay because the alpha the coefficient of X-four represented marginal utility of X-one and the beta represented marginal utility of X-two so the marginal rate of substitution is still exactly the same and in every one of these it's exactly the same mathematically but in this case it doesn't change it's it's going to remain exactly constant what sort of goods demonstrate would have that sort of of er indifference curve what we're saying is that your margin utility okay doesn't change according to how much you have and the rate at which you substitute between the two goods remains exactly the same so if you alwa-, you will always require for example two units of X-one to replace one unit of X-two have you got any idea of the sorts of goods we might see that with how substitutable are these goods do you think very substitutable or not very substitutable very yeah these are perfect substitutes okay that doesn't mean that the marginal rate of substitution is one I-E one unit for one unit one unit of X-one for one unit of X-two but it does mean that the rate of substitution doesn't change at all it remains exactly the same hence they are perfect substitutes for one another and that remains exactly the the same however much you have and a function that would represent that is simply alpha- X-one plus beta-X-two okay the marginal rate of substitution is again alpha over beta it's the ratio okay of of the two because alpha's the marginal utility of X-one beta's u-, marginal utility of X-two but in this case it remains it's it's a constant okay er however much X-one or X-two the consumer has these are perfect substitutes for one another okay these of course are easy to handle 'cause they're linear it's a very s-, simple function but again all we're saying is that if that was if we had two goods for which the consumer you know er regarded them as perfectly er substitutable then that that would represent that okay alpha-X-one plus beta-X-two and so that is the perfect substitute case which is one extreme away from the convex er indifference curves that we we saw before the other extreme i-, is as follows right-angled indifference curves have you any idea what sort of grid this might be because you may have seen demand curves that look exactly like this in the past sf0760: right and left shoe nm0757: sorry sf0760: [cough] left shoe and right shoe nm0757: left shift and right shift sf0760: left left left shoe and right shoe nm0757: oh left shoe and right shoe er not necessarily no mm maybe maybe what what do you mean by that sf0760: nm0757: okay yeah mayb-, yeah okay so what are you saying about the two goods sf0760: nm0757: mm sf0760: you mean like one or the other nm0757: okay in which case yeah can you think of any other examples these these goods are perfect complements yeah that is that they are consumed in certain combinations so in fact you're right left shoes right shoes er exactly the same er if someone likes er black coffee then they don't have any milk if they like very milky coffee then they they they consume a certain amount of milk in their coffee but the two cannot compensate for one another okay they can't compensate for one another so if you have so you're right if you have a left shoe then you have then have a right shoe that's fine but if you then have one extra right shoe that doesn't actually give you any more satisfaction because you need another left shoe presumably to consume with it or if you like a certain combination of of milk and and coffee in a drink if you add more milk then you don't get any extra satisfaction and that combination is that point there okay that combination says well in this case you require equal amounts of X-one and X-two so it could be left and right shoes for example okay er you have to consume them in that combination if you have more X-one okay which is going out along here you don't get any more satisfaction at all it remains exactly the same 'cause you don't go to another indifference curve and likewise if you have more X-two you don't get any more satisfaction you remain on the same indifference curve okay so the only way you get more satisfaction is to move up here on a line with the same combinations of X-one and X-two I-E you need more of both goods in exactly the same ratio to get more satisfaction if you get more of one and no more of the other you don't get any more satisfaction at all because you m-, you need to consume the two goods together okay now this is the other extreme of course perfect complements perfect substitutes it is however slightly er unrealistic i-, in in some senses because what we're saying is that if the consumer has this amount of the two goods so like milk and coffee so in this case the consumer would have white very milky coffee in the sense that they require the same quantities of both okay half and half what we're then saying is okay if this consumer was given coffee with more and more milk the amount of satisfaction they get doesn't go up it doesn't go down okay so they don't get any extra satisfaction but they don't get disutility either now that is probably unrealistic because what probably happens actually is that they require in this case same amount of milk the same amount of coffee but if they get more or less of one their actual utility goes down okay because the coffee gets more and more milk they don't like it hence their level of satisfaction goes down okay and we're assuming having the green lines here that that doesn't happen okay so they're perfect complements but if they get out of synch with one another they er you don't get disutility if you get disutility then in fact the indifference curve would simply be the points okay up here because the goods would have to be consumed in absolutely those quantities any other spoils everything okay so in certain cases extreme cases it could be that you have to consume them in absolute quantities in the same ratio or you got no utility at all okay [cough] and we're assuming here that that's not quite the extreme okay there is there are these combinations you have to consume them in but if you don't then er you don't get disutility but you don't get any more utility okay how we represent this algebraically is with a very strange function which is minimum alpha-X-one comma beta-X-two that is the again alpha is the marginal utility of X-one beta is the marginal utility of X-two the ratio between them will give you the marginal rate of substitution er but imagine utility is entirely determined by the good okay which is in the lowest amount okay so there may be excess amounts of one good so you might have say ten units of coffee and thirty units of milk but clearly you'd only use er ten units of milk because you'd need it to go in the coffee okay you'd you could use them in in equal amounts the excess amount of milk doesn't give any diss-, dissatisfaction but it doesn't give any satisfaction and so the amount of utility the consumer gets is entirely con-, er constrained by the amount of coffee the thing that's in short supply okay and that's the sort of function that would would represent that okay so what we're saying is that we can represent all types of of preference er perfect substitutes like that er perfect complements like that and the normal case with convex indifference curves like that and what we do is to represent these er types of preference okay mathematically and all we're saying is that if we look at the preferences that consumers have the way in which they trade off between the goods that are available to them and we observe that for some goods that have o-, er substitutes that is the consumer er doesn't really care which they have and will trade off between them at a rate that doesn't change or if we observe their perfect complements the other extreme these goods are always consumed in exactly the same quantities okay in a particular combination because that's how the two go together to produce something else and on their own they don't give any utillity or the middle case which is w-, w-, what we would normally er observe we think that in fact the goods are not perfect complements or per-, perfect substitutes there is substitutability between the two goods the amount of substitutability will depend on the slope so the flatter this indifference curve is this board's getting worse so if it was like that that would mean act-, actually there's not that much s-, er er sorry there's a lot of substitutability between those goods okay 'cause it's it's getting towards flat it does change but not that much so we'd be erring in this direction here okay and maybe if we had indifference curves that were like that we'd now erring in this direction here towards perfect complements so the the slope of the indifference curve of course differs but we do have these two extremes perfect substitutes and perfect complements okay er we can represent these so if we observe these types of preference we can represent them in an algebraic way using functions that we've just looked at okay they're ordinal functions which means that all that matters is the higher the number the higher the indifference curve it means that if we have a number er which is higher for example we'd be on this indifference curve rather than that one perhaps we're not saying how much they differ we're not saying we can measure utility we are not saying that if the number is higher that means the consumer gets twice the amount of utility we're not doing that because we know we can't measure utility but also we don't need to if all we're interested in is how much of the goods the consumer consumes 'cause that's what we're interested in the choice the consumer makes which we assume is meas-, is driven by utility okay they want to maximize then the the degree to which they meet their needs and wants we measure that as this idea of utility or preference whatever we don't actually need to measure preference or utility in a c-, in a cardinal sense all we need to know is that the consumer does get the highest level of utility they possibly can okay and to do that we represent these preferences using these mathematical forms okay the mathematical form we use depends on the type of preferences we see if they're perfect substitutes then we use the type of function that we've just looked at okay er alpha-X-one plus alpha er plus beta-X-two if we observe they're perfect complements we use minimum alpha-X-one beta-X-two more normally we would er we would have preferences like in in the middle case they would differ in the amount of substitutability complementarity and that would be represented in the alpha and beta values but we would use a function which was er X-one -to-the-alpha X-two- to-the-beta which is the normal form we would use those am-, those the values of alpha and beta represent the marginal utilities and therefore the ratio represents the marginal rate of substitution and that will differ according to all the goods that the consumer has and will differ between every consumer according to their preferences okay but all we're saying is that we can represent now these ideas that we've built up the ideas on preference and the the the properties that preferences have in a in a mathematical sense which means we can do it for any number of goods we want we're not constrained to three which we are here and we can now put it together and we can actually produce something that will allow us to measure the marginal rate of substitution which is a useful piece of information to predict the choices that a consumer will make in particular circumstances which is vaguely interesting most interesting we can put it together to u-, to build up a model that allows us to predict what happens if things change if this is what the consumer chooses now what happens if something a factor that influences their choices changes prices go up income goes down whatever that is very useful 'cause it allows us to derive elasticities for example and that is useful information somebody who wants to market a product wants to know if i increase my price ten per cent how much does demand change will my revenue go up or will my revenue go down what happens if my competitor changes their price reduces their price by five per cent how much is the demand for my product going to change so being able to represent all of this these notions in an algebraic sense allows us to to produce that sort of model okay and that's what we want to do okay let's take a a break there and then when we come back what we're going to do is to put the two sides together okay nm0757: this choice process can be broken down into two parts the things the the combinations of the goods that the consumer is able to buy and if you remember we said that that the first of all the availability part is determined by their budget line which is equal to P-one-X-one plus P-two -X-two er is smaller or equal to M so they cannot consume any combination of these goods which they can't afford the slope of that line is is equal to p-one over p-two the ratio of the prices the price of X-one over the price of X-two this is the same for every consumer the consumer is a minor part of the total market they double their consumption demand doesn't change price doesn't change that is the same for everyone the position of this line is determined by their income okay the higher their income the further out it is the lower their income the further in it is if there's zero income then the clearly they will be at that point there presuming there are no free goods there are no goods that don't cost anything okay we also had these non-negativities here and here it's not possible to consume negative amounts of goods and this one here we said X-two must be greater or equal to nought and here X-one must be greater or equal to normal so you can't consume anything less than zero which is at the origin that is the availability set what they can consume given the prices of the goods given their income prices change this changes and the slope of the budget line changes their income changes the slope remains the same and we just move in in and out that's what we looked at er a while ago now their availability set then the other part their preferences what do they want to consume okay and just like here we looked at what was available to them regardless of what they wanted to do what we've just done is to look at what they want to do regardless of what they can do okay regardless of what they they have available to them and we've said that that is driven consumption behaviour is induced motivated by your needs and wants consumers' needs and wants and we have the it's driven by the idea of preferences that is a c-, the consumer prefers a good that meets more of their needs and wants than one that pref-, that that meets less of their needs and wants so it's totally motivated behaviour and we can represent that through indifference curves and the direction of the consumer's preferences given non- satiation is out in this direction so they want to get out as far as possible out here as they can these these preferences exhibit things like transitivity we have a convex er indifference curve which means that we have a rate of trade off between the good and the marginal rate of substitution which changes according to the amount of the goods that they consume so these are in this case some substitutability between the goods but they're not they're not perfect er complements okay but they're not perfect substitutes and that we can represent that these these preferences u-, using a utility function an ordinal function which is U -X-one-X-two and we can the mathematical form of that function will depend on what the preferences look like whether they're perfect substitutes perfect complements or like this in the normal type and we'll use the mathematical form which satisfies that which which has that that has those properties given that the consumer aims to consume as much of these goods as possible they're non-satiating we said the consumer and the idea of rationality we came up with in the first week is that the consumer aims to maximize their satisfaction okay aims to maximize the degree to which their needs and wants are satisfied and so what we're saying is on this diagram they've aimed for the highest indifference curve they want the one that's as high as possible because that's the one that gives them the highest level of utility or we want to maximize the value of their utility function 'cause the higher that is the higher the indifference curve they're on okay putting it together then we have what they want to do they want to aim to get that the the con-, th-, they want to consume as much X-one and X-two as possible and in the realm of all the goods as much of those goods as possible however many are available to them they want to maximize their utility they want to consume that combination of goods and services that gives them the greatest satisfaction meets as much of their needs and wants as possible but they're constrained in doing so because these goods are not free they have to pay for them and their ability to pay for them is constrained by their income okay the extent to which they're constrained depends on what their income is and how much the goods are but they are constrained in doing this and if we put those two together okay that's a consumer's budget line f-, for for an individual consumer okay and it will be the same slope for all consumers but the position will depend on how much income they have so all the consumers have the same level of income it'll be in the same position those that have more income it'll be further out those that have low income will be further in okay that's their availability set and we have these indifference curves which represent their preferences okay let's just call them U-one to U-three and what they will do is to choose that combination of goods that gives them the highest level of utility gives the maximum preferences given the resources that are available to them and that will occur at the point where the budget line just touches the highest indifference curve and that is the choice that the consumer will make so that's the quantity of X- one and that's the quantity of X-two that the consumer will be able to consume okay so what we're saying is that given the the constraints on the choice choices that the consumer can make which is t-, t-, which are totally outside of their control they are economic constraints okay on er basically how much of these goods they can consume determined by the market prices and by their income and at any point in time those things are fixed of course someone can have influenced their income in the longer term work longer hours for example er can save at one point in time so they have more resources in the future and so on but at any point in time when the consumer chooses so when they're in the supermarket whatever then those are are fixed things the prices are fixed and their income is fixed and what we're saying is that how they decide between all the combinations of goods they can buy within those constraints is by thinking about how much all the different combinations will meet their needs and wants and they will be driven to choose that combination that provides the greatest utility that combination that meets their needs and wants most effectively we've represented that through a series of indifference curves and they're i i o-, we emphasize again we're not saying that the consumer goes into the supermarket with indifference curves or utility functions whatever what we're saying is we can represent how they make their choices in this way okay in this s-, sort of abstract model and putting the two sides together it will be the point at which the budget line just touches their highest indifference curve okay and that will be the choice they make that amount of X-one that amount of X-two okay if their income changes the choice will change if the price of any of the goods changes their choice will change if their preferences change then the choice may change okay so if there's an advertising campaign about one of the goods say X-one that shifts their preferences so they like X- one more then their choice may change okay and we're going to look at those sorts of changes er next week er but those are the sorts of er changes that might go on and that would be reflected in a shift in the position of that point the choice that the consumer actually makes okay now we can represent that also er algebraically by just putting together these elements here okay because we've been able we've said to represent mathematically these the indifference curves through this utility function and the availability set through this budget constraint and through these non- negativities so you can't consume negative amounts and so we can represent this mathematically it is simply that we want to maximize that utility function okay we want to be on the highest indifference curve possible that's how you want to think about it we want to maximize the utility the consumer gets and what we've done is to represent that through this utility function whatever its mathematical form and all that mathematical form does is to represent the way in which the consumer thinks about the goods the preferences the consumer has perfect complements perfect substitutes anything in between and that will depend on the individual one individual may regard products as perfect substitutes and another individual may not okay but all we're doing is representing how they see those goods in some mathematical sense and we'll maximize that okay and that would go to infinity if they weren't constrained but they are they're subject to two basic constraints the first is the budget line so they can maximize this freely until they hit this they can't spend more than they earn okay so they hit this budget line and secondly the non-negativities you can't consume less than zero of a good however much you hate it [cough] now that is obvious in real life but mathematically we have to allow for all eventualities because what we've now done is to say okay we can represent all these things that we can see go on and the assumptions we've made and what we can do is we can er now represent that this in this way because it's now mathematical we of course have to stop it doing stupid things okay when we run this and so we have to include those and that is the basic model that says what the consumer will do when faced with all of the goods and services that are available to them is they will select between those goods and services on the basis of their own personal preferences and we can represent those preferences in the mathematical sense okay and that mathematical representation will encapsulate will include all of the properties that we have observed okay in consumer preferences things like transitivity things like non-satiation things like the fact that the marginal rate of substitution diminishes er as or changes as the amount of the goods change because the marginal utility's changed all of those things that we can see okay er and which we know we think influence the way in which pe-, er people trade off the goods that they based we can represent that in within this and the mathematical form we use okay will depend on what we observed okay perfect substitutes we've one form perfect complements another form any other er type we use another form relative values of alpha and beta will again reflect those trade offs how much they like the two goods and how that rate of trade off changes as you get more and less of the goods okay so all of that can be represented and that's all that is doing is representing the way in which the consumer makes those choices again we're not saying that's how they make them we're saying that we can represent it in that way and they can do that they c-, they make their choices but they're constrained in so doing because well first of all the non-negativities which are fairly obvious but they're constrained by just economic facts of life the fact that they face these prices which are non- zero so they have to pay for the goods and that's out of their control as an individual consumer okay and they also face their income which at any point in time when they make a choice is fixed okay it will depend on their money income from employment from other sources it will depend on their savings decisions in the past er access to credit and and all that but th-, at the point they make their choice will be fixed okay and so what we've done is to break down er the choices into these two parts and pu-, pulled together er the parts that we consider most important okay now of course this model er includes and there are certain elements of it include an awful lot of factors like utility preferences will include an awful lot of things that influence preferences like advertising access to information your own attitudes and beliefs about er the product about the world whatever and those will change over time and they will be different between individuals every individual will be different and hence this will change but at the point where the consumer stands in the supermarket or or whatever that is fixed okay at the point at which they make the choice the next time they make the choice that may be different that's okay but at the point that they make the choice that will be fixed just like this is fixed and we might be interested in knowing how this differs and the impact of changes in this okay and that's fine so we might be interested in looking at well if a consumer makes a choice now and then they make it next week after there's been an advertising campaign whatever we might be interested in knowing how that has changed okay that may be one of the variables that we want to consider but at the point they make the choice standing there that is fixed okay likewise these may change from week to week month to month or whatever but at the point where they're facing a choice at any point in time those are fixed and so what we've done is represent the choices that the consumer makes in this this algebraic sense what that allows us to do is to mathematically er look at the choices people make we can look at the prices people face the incomes they face we can represent their preferences through some utility function and we look at choice okay that combination of the two goods in this case that the consumer's likely to choose and we can then use that model to look at what happens if things change if the price of X-one doubles what's going to happen are they going to stop consuming X-one altogether or do they like X-one so much that they only reduce their consumption by a little bit and so on okay so that's what we can we can do with this we can also represent er the optimal point okay we can consider what happens at the point where they actually made their choices let me er quickly put this down again okay so that's the point at which they make their that's the optimal point okay and we can consider what are what what are the conditions er which must be satisfied for for the consumer to be at an optimum for them to actually be ma-, achieving the maximum level of satisfaction they can and there are two basic conditions first of all they must be using all of their income okay because we're assuming that we've included within our framework all of the things that give utility and remember this is a world where people get utility from consumption we can include if people like lots of money in the bank we can include that as well because we can include savings as a source of utility that's that's okay but what we have done is we've included within their utility function within the idea of our indifference curves everything that gives them satisfaction and hence at the end of the day they must allocate all of their incomings to to those things that give them satisfaction including maybe savings so first of all that must be the case their expenditure which is this that's their total expenditure must equal their money income okay that's the first thing that must be er must occur so that means they're going to be on their budget line okay providing we've included everything in the in here that gives them utility they must be on their budget line because they don't get any utility from not allocating their income that's the first er er thing we would we would see so their expenditure's not going to be less than their income it's going to be exactly equal to it of course it can't be more the second is that they are at this point here okay they're at that point there okay that means that the slope of the budget line is equal to the slope of the indifference curve okay 'cause at that point there they're going to be exactly the same the slope of their budget line and the slope of their indifference curve are going to be exactly the same and that's the second condition okay what is the slope of the budget line equal to sm0761: inverse price ratio nm0757: sorry sm0761: inverse price ratio nm0757: okay so it's the ratio of the prices yeah so the slope of that at any point is equal to p-one over p-two and it's exactly constant of course it's a straight line the prices do not depend on how much the the er consumer chooses so that one's linear that's a straight line what's the slope of the indifference curve what's the marginal rate of substitution sf0762: it's the ratio of marginal utility nm0757: okay it's the ratio of the marginal utility so the the slope of this is equal to marg utility of X-one over marg utility of X-two and at the optimum they must be equal okay the ratio of prices must be equal to the ratio of the marginal utility okay now you you know that that is equal to the marginal rate of substitution okay but in fact that is what is termed the marginal rate for substitution in consumption what it is is the rate at which the consumer wants to substitute between the goods given their preferences how they feel about the goods that is the rate at which they are willing to trade off between them okay or willing to trade off X-one and X-two or whatever goods we're dealing with okay so given their preferences that is the rate at which they are willing to trade them off and at this and it this is at that point there it depends on how much of the two goods because we this is convex to the origin so this differs this changes when diminishes as we move from the top to the bottom this is also the marginal rate of substitution this is the marginal rate of substitution in exchange it is the rate at which they are able to trade off the two goods and that is totally determined by their relative prices so the rate at which you are able to trade off one good for another depends on their relative price if one good is er costs you know a pound and another good costs fifty pence clearly then you can have you know two of the goods that cost fifty pence or one of the goods that cost a pound and that is totally determined by the prices out of your control okay but that is your your marginal rate of substitution all consumers' marginal rate of substitution in exchange is determined by the market place determined by the collective decisions of the suppliers and of all consumers but for you as an individual it's fixed because you are irrelevant within the market as a consumer and so at the optimal point we're saying that the rate at which the consumer is able to substitute between the goods determined by market prices is exactly equal to the rate at which they want to consu-, to to substitute between them which is determined by their ratio of marginal utilities okay so at the optimum it is the case that the marginal rate of substitution in exchange is exactly equal to the marginal rate of substitution in consumption the rate at which the consumers are able to substitute between the goods through market transactions is exactly equal to the rate at which they wish to substitute between them given their preferences okay the implication of that is that if we we order this we change this around okay what we find is that just rejigging this around we find that in fact that is equal to this expression here that at the optimum the ratio of the marginal utilities to the unit prices of the goods is exactly equal for every good that is the amount of utility you get for every unit of money spent is exactly the same for all of the goods okay so the marginal utility the amount of utility you get from consuming one extra unit of the good the ratio of that to the price that is how much it costs you to consume one extra unit of the good at the optimum is exactly equal for all of the goods you consume so the amount of utility for one unit of money is the same for X-one and for X-two can anyone remember what that is called you've done this in part one anyone remember this is termed the equimarginal principle okay if you remember you did it in part one with er looking at cardinal theory wi-, of consumer choice you said that what the d-, consumer does is they allocate their the goods and we assumed then we could measure it but what they did was they do it in such a way that the amount of income sorry the amount of utility they get for each of the for for the er unit amount of money they spend is the same for all the goods so it's not possible to allocate your money between the goods and get any extra utility so therefore you must be at the optimum okay you cannot reallocate your income in any way given the price of the goods and given the your preferences for those goods and achieve any extra utility this is called the equimarginal principle which you'll have met before so we end up in the s-, t-, in the same position okay as with other ideas but we're not measuring utility now we've represented it in a far more sophisticated model that we can actually applo-, employ to estimate things like elasticities to predict demand change in demand whatever but fundamentally it's based on the principle that consumers given their choices are driven by preferences that are individual to them and given they're constrained by their economic circumstances they will allocate their income in such a way given their preferences that they cannot achieve any extra utility they can't meet any more of their needs and wants by jigging around their er their their allocation of their income between the goods this is also equal to U-M the marginal utility of their money income if the consumer was given a fractional increase in their money income okay at the optimum it wouldn't matter which good they bought more of their extra marginal utility would be exactly the same because it has been equated across the groups ratio of the marginal utilities to their money their money to their prices it's exactly the same so if they were given a fractional increase in income it wouldn't matter which good they allocated it to simply because the ratio of marginal utility to prices is the same for every one of them and so that is at the margin the marginal utility of their money income of money okay so what we've done is to build up a model which we can represent okay diagrammatically for up to three goods but we've built it up taking account of all of the characteristics of consumer preferences and of their economic constraints okay that that you know really matter yes sure we have put a lot of things together like the indifference curve represents all of those things well includes all those things that influence the consumer's preferences every one of those is included within that and any one of those if it changes will change that indifference curve okay that's fine we've equally included the economic constraints okay and what we've now done is put them together to produce a model which we hope will allow us to okay on the f-, on the one hand predict the choice this consumer will make in this circumstance which is vaguely interesting what is more interesting is if we then use this to say okay what happens if things change can we use this given that we can now represent it er mathematically so we can actually represent it like this so we could given we can represent this mathematically we could apply this to data from the real world price data income data et cetera we so we can actually put real data into this when we've put it in an empirical model a-, and predict what will happen and what will happen if things change so now we can do that and to prove that this model er really does sort of encapsulate the way in which at least economists see the choices consumer makes the consumer makes again we're not saying this is how the consumer does make it we're sort of abstracting from the real world and trying to encapsulate how they make choices in a model that we can we can use that at that point they will spend all their income 'cause of another black holes that give utility and at that point they will maximize their utility they will not be able to reallocate their income in such a way that they can meet more of their needs and wants and so the rate at which they are able to substitute between the goods within the marketplace through through their market transactions is just equal to the rate at which they wish t-, to substitute between those goods and that gives us the principle the-, the marginal principle which says that the ratio of the marginal utility to price is the same for all of the goods so if the consumer's given a fractional increase in income it wouldn't matter which of the goods they allocated it to 'cause it would be exactly the same okay so that is the basic the basic model that we've built up and it encapsulates all of the things that we we have said we think we observe in the real world so the ideas of diminishing marginal rate of substitution because of changes in er marginal utilities okay er the ideas of non-satiation transitivity all of those are encapsulated here 'cause we've built up the indifference curves and therefore are encapsulated here 'cause we can now represent them in a mathematical sense and the availability set which we we've said applies to the consumer the economic constraints they face so we've put all that together and we've produced this rather simple model the complication with it comes when you want to actually employ it in practice and we're not going to look at that in great detail because there you're getting into complex statistical procedures econometric procedures relating to the mathematical form that this takes okay and how we can put it together into something we can estimate what we're now going to do next week is to look at how we can use this okay we've said this is how we can model the choice they make okay I-E remember what we're saying is what we can observe in the real world is the prices the income and what people choose okay they're the things we can see we can see what people buy because we can actually collect that information we could do it on an individual basis 'cause we could ask people we could er ask them to give us their till receipts from the supermarket we could follow them around the shop we can gather that information in many ways we can do it on a collective basis of all consumers by looking at how much er how many bananas Sainsbury's and Tesco et cetera sell or at a national account level we can gather that information so we can look at what people choose I-E the X-one and X-two we can look at prices because again we can gather that information what the prices are in the shops and we can gather information on income so we can get all the variables income prices and choice we can get all of those and what we are go-, what we do is to use this model to make sense of those choices and when we've used this model to make sense of those choices I-E we use this model to understand why they've made the choices they have for example to discover what their preferences are we can then use that to say okay how much do we what do we think the consumption of bananas is going to be next year if we expect the prices to go up ten per cent and we expect people's incomes to go up say three four per cent what's the demand for bananas likely to be is it going to be higher is it going to be lower and by how much and that's useful so we're going to look at what happens if things change okay and what measures can we produce of those changes so things like elasticities er for example okay let's leave it there