nm0638: you may remember last time we were talking about some key aspects of natural resource use er we said that we would look at the element of scarcity we looked at time and dynamics and the effect that those things have on resource use we looked at technology we spent a few minutes talking about property rights and then we had a bit of a recap looking at various sources of uncertainty er surrounding our decisions concerning the use of natural resources over time we return to the issue of scarcity and we started off by saying that really the the fundamental resource use issue is that we have a rapidly rising global population increasing economic activity by that population resulting in a declining resource base and an increased production of wastes and therefore an increased burden if you like on the environment to assimilate those wastes so that's where we left it last time this time i want to continue to explore this issue of scarcity a little bit more and then to go on to develop a very simple framework er where we can actually try and determine the optimum resource use er over time you may remember at the start of last week where we were reminding ourselves of the role of economists in the environment and resource use we said well this is the simple view of the world that economists have we look at resources as inputs to the production system they're transformed into goods and services that we want to consume and we said that really that was a rather inadequate framework when we start to want to consider environmental issues within economics because what we have in fact is a whole series of waste products produced not only by the production system itself but b-, by the very process of getting resources for instance out of the ground from mining resources and from the process of consumption we produce all sorts of wastes from these three elements associated with the production process and we have no economic framework within which we can directly consider the problem of producing wastes we noted last week that what we called these things were externalities negative externalities problems that lie outside effectively of our normal economic framework and which somehow now we need to take account of because these things are causing us problems okay look a little bit of science mixed in with economics here the first law of thermo-, thermodynamics really just says that energy and matter can't be destroyed energy and matter can't be destroyed so that ultimately the resources that you use will end up being various types of different waste one thing that we know that we can do for many natural resources is to actually recycle some of these wastes and get back some of the resource input that we can then use again so if we want to start to incorporate those elements into our simple framework it might look something like this so here's our resource inputs the production process consumption that's our standard economic model we note the production of wastes from this process but now we've added another element that we can actually recycle some of these wastes to produce more resources there are two things that this diagram takes account of in addition one is the second law of thermodynamics which just says that resources are used entropically in other words they're dissipated so think of the use of oil say fossil fuel like oil it has loads of different outputs doesn't it it produces energy that we want yes but it produces loads of other emissions in all sorts of of other by-products C-O-two and so on and you can't capture those back combine them again and get the fossil fuel back the oil back again can you that's obvious resources are used entropically they get dissipated some dissipated into the environment and so on so this simple formula here is just saying that you can never recapture however good you are at recycling your waste you can never recapture the whole amount of the resource again which is pretty obvious i guess and that's what this diagram takes account of because here it says look however good your recycling some of these wastes are going to end up in the environment into the into the sink if you like of the environment we talk about environmental sinks the other thing this diagram takes account of is the fact that recycling itself is a resource using activity okay recycling itself is a resource using activity which is why we've got this red dotted line yeah showing that there's a resource input into the recycling process itself and occasionally you get crazy situations where recycling is such a great idea people think that they actually end up using more resources in the recycling process than they're actually saving okay any questions about that okay let's have a a brief and very simplistic look because these two sessions are introductory sessions for this course a brief and and rather simplistic look at natural resources and their characteristics and very very briefly i'm going to look at air land minerals water ecological resources and i probably won't look at er solar power or or sun to any great extent at all so if we start looking at air first i said it was going to be simplistic why is air important to us well first of all it's a source of nutrients for plant and animal species secondly it's a sink for pollutants we pump all sorts of stuff into the air don't we use it as a sink for pollutants it's important for atmospheric protection in the climate system it's an important energy resource wind power and it's im-, an important spatial medium to state the obvious and these figures aren't really worth getting down because they're just illustrative and i've already given you some ideas of reading and the United Nations er Environment Programme website where you can get er data like this probably more up to date data now as well but i just picked out some pollution figures for some of the major cities of the world so we've got London Sydney Montreal New York Beijing and Delhi and this first column looks at the number of days of the year when sulphur dioxide levels are above a certain limit think that's a hundred-and-fifty micrograms per metre cubed and we know that above that limit it will have a negative effect on human health on the far column here we've got the level of particulate matter yeah particles in the air er again the number of days that they're over a certain critical level and again that critical level we know will cause health problems in the population so you can see in London over the time that this survey was er taken er out of the year seventeen seventeen days in London where S-O-two levels were too high eleven in Sydney thirty-two Montreal twenty-two New York a hundred-and-fifty-seven in Beijing forty-nine in Delhi so not surprisingly er a city like Beijing er far more polluted than a city like Sydney in terms of sulphur dioxide at least and in fact when you start to look at particulate matter and these are particles that will have all sorts of deposits attached to them er some will be er cancer causing er chemicals et cetera et cetera have all sorts of impacts on human health er lung diseases bronchitis all these sorts of things three-hundred-and- thirty-eight days nearly every day of the year er over the time this survey was taken in Beijing and Delhi were these particulate matter days over that critical limit and the U-N has worked out then that over six- hundred-million people live in cities where the sulphur dioxide level is having a bad effect on their health and one-and-a-quarter-billion people are in cities with unacceptable particulate matter so there's a lot of people living in an environment an air environment that is pretty bad for their health okay so those figures were taken out of the World Resources book that i showed you last last week again as part of our introduction let's have a quick look at land as a resource again obviously land an important spatial entity that we use to build on et cetera et cetera an important medium for example for crop growth an important source of other natural resources mineral resources and so on and again it's a sink for pollutants so in terms of its value to us what are the important characteristics of land what sorts of characteristics attributes of land are important to us any ideas yeah sf0639: it's in fixed supply nm0638: it's in fixed supply and that's sure that's the economist in you responding there isn't it yeah okay it's in fixed supply but what attributes what characteristics mean that land is either very valuable to us or not very valuable to us or very useful to us or not very useful to us yeah sf0640: fertility nm0638: sorry sf0640: fertility nm0638: yeah okay fertility level of fertility in the soil anything else sm0641: whether it's flat or kind of steep and slopey nm0638: yeah okay so the topography of of the land yeah anything else sm0642: climate and microclimate nm0638: yeah okay climate so climate topography altitude these things are are linked of course er soil you mentioned anything else sm0643: its geography to other compared to other sources nm0638: yeah okay so its location is going to be important whether it's located near er another er important natural resource like a water resource like a river or the sea or whatever for instance and of course property rights important for all resources we said but particularly associated with with land as a resource and again i've just picked out a few figures looking at land use across the world so looking at er the percentage of crop land pasture land forest er and wilderness which is quite interesting throughout the world so not surprisingly er Europe thirty per cent of Europe is down to crops eighteen per cent to pasture thirty-three per cent to forest er and only four per cent is total wilderness so nineteen per cent will be land that's built on and all other land yeah including swamp desert et cetera so if you compare Europe with a country well with an area rather rather rather a region such as South America here we've got relatively little crop land overall eight per cent quite a lot of pasture yeah a lot of range management twenty-seven per cent lot of forest fifty-two per cent we know there's a lot important er forest resources in South America and quite a lot of wilderness too twenty-four per cent i think the U-N classified wilderness er as an area that had no signs of man's activities at all so there's no roads no habitations er no teleph-, telecommunications or or anything so no no sign of their er o-, of man's input at all and here's a quite an interesting contrast here for the U-S and Canada which have totally different figures the U-S r-, r-, relatively population dense compared with with Canada er so Canada sixty-five per cent of Canada is classified as total wilderness but of course a lot of those areas are very very cold areas in the far north okay so a a global idea of of land use i thought those figures might be useful to get things into perspective into context and while we're talking about forestry i just dug out a few figures on on forestry that might be interesting don't know whether we can see this but i'll talk you through it anyway a diagram here just showing the area of closed forests cleared annually in various tropical countries in the nineteen-eighties i've got some nineteen-nineties figures to see how things have changed in the nineteen-nineties so closed forests where there's a where there's a closed canopy over the top so you can see for instance that throughout the nineteen- eighties Brazil was clearing over two per cent of its forest closed forest area every year yeah so if you carried on at that sort of rate then you can see that fifty or sixty years and you've virtually cleared the whole lot if you carried on at that rate depending on replanting of course India four-point-one per cent every year of closed forest Costa Rica here seven- point-six per cent of its closed forest being cleared every year in the nineteen-eighties so you can see that deforestation was maybe still is we'll see er a real problem certainly up until the nineteen-eighties so what's been done about that since well these are updated figures sorry they're a bit scruffy this is for the nineteen-ninety to ninety-five period when in South America well it we only had Brazil before er two-point-two per cent but South America overall er losing at just point-five of w-, one half of one per cent every year yeah zero-point-five per cent a year Asia zero-point-seven per cent a year Central America still er relatively er rapid compared with other regions one-point-three per cent a year but nothing like the seven-point-six per cent that it was er back in the nineteen-eighties Africa point-seven per cent Europe is actually increasing its forest area slightly point-three per cent so these are total figures they take account of afforestation a-, as well so they're not directly comparable but certainly countries areas of the world have taken action because y-, you know to try and slow down the rate of deforestation but at a global level yeah the net effect is still that we are losing trees on the planet at a rate of around point-three per cent er a year we've got two other resource types that i want to look at er sorry three other fairly briefly the next is a quick look at mineral resources and one simple classification of mineral resources might be into whether they are metallic or non-metallic so the metallic resources we're talking about relatively abundant resources such as iron iron ore and of course there are relativis-, relatively scarce ones such as copper gold and so on on the non-metallic side we can look at the different uses to which non-metallic resources are put so we can classify them into for instance whether they're used for chemical uses of one sort and another given the example of nitrates whether they're used for building purposes clay cement sand and of course the important fossil fuels that are used to produce energy like oil and coal and so we're when we're looking at this issue of scarcity it's a fairly relative term isn't it and i've got some figures here that i thought were interesting and i haven't updated them because i haven't er managed to get hold of comparable data i wanted to update them to ninety-eight and they didn't actually produce comparable data so i so i couldn't do that but although this data is over ten years old it still still makes the point it looks at sort of major region in terms of production and consumption er of iron ore major regions in the world and it looks at the world total the interesting thing to look at are these two figures the reserves and the reserve base and i think this is a very useful way of thinking about the scarcity of a resource it looks at the life-years left of the resource at current rates of consumption so of reserves that are at the moment economically viable to actually mine in nineteen-eighty-eight there were a hundred-and-sixty-seven years worth of iron ore left in the world but there are other reserves that we know about that at the moment or at least in nineteen-eighty-eight weren't economically viable to mine and if you included those all known reserves then there's over two-hundred years two-hundred-and- thirty-six years worth of iron ore in the world but it could cost you quite a lot to get it all of it and the smudgy question that i had written down here was to what extent did these figures take account of recycling and i didn't find the answer to that i'm afraid from the U-N figures clearly if you stepped up your recycling programme then er effectively you can reduce your level of consumption and er increase your your life-years from your resource so that's iron ore relatively abundant we've got over two- hundred years worth probably of known reserves there are probably other reserves that we haven't found yet here's a different resource again the only figures that you might want to take down in your notes are these life-, er life-year figures here we can see with z- , with zinc a relatively scarce metallic mineral total known reserves regardless of how much it costs us to get the stuff out of the ground only forty-two years in nineteen-eighty-eight and only half of that were actually economically viable to mine in nineteen-eighty-eight just twenty-one years so in terms of relative scarcity er zinc a relatively scarce mineral resource compared with iron ore fairly obviously and what i was particularly interested in is finding out the estimation of this figure today ten years on does that really mean today that we have less than ten years worth of reserves of zinc left if i can find the figure i i will i'll let you know just a few other quick illustrative figures on life-years you won't be able to see all this but i will er point out the interesting bit looking at fossil fuels just quickly running through here looking at the life-years left again in nineteen-eighty-eight looking at current levels then of er consumption looking at oil just ten years worth in North America apparently over fifty years in Latin America Middle East they couldn't even estimate it they just put a hundred years plus in the Middle East lucky old Middle East so a relatively scarce resource certainly for North America and Western Europe here what about natural gas again North America fourteen years Western Europe thirty-four years er Middle East again a hundred plus years Africa a hundred plus years so the world totals at the bottom here forty-one years worth of er reserves of oil global oil reserves fifty-eight years worth of natural gas apparently and when you look at coal we've got over two-hundred years worth of coal reserves in the in in the world so coal a relatively abundant resource compared with oil and natural gas so in Western Europe again we've got over two-hundred years worth of coal reserves Africa's got three-hundred-and-fifty years worth and so on relatively abundant sorry so that was our quick look into into minerals let's have an even quicker look at water as a resource and if you haven't done this exercise before it's quite illuminating write down all the the uses all the reasons why water is valuable to us all the uses for water what do we use water for and all the reasons why it might be valuable to us we'll see what we've got in a couple of minutes nm0638: okay what have we got who wants to start us off anyone uses of water sf0644: energy nm0638: energy sf0644: yeah nm0638: yeah okay we'll come on to that in a minute sm0645: drinking nm0638: yes thank you for stating the obvious one first on my list yeah okay er i've called it potable supplies drinking water supplies because of course in in many countries certainly in this country we use drinking quality water to do all sorts of things with not just drink so we wash ourselves in drinking quality water we wash our clothes in drinking quality water we sprinkle our gardens with drinking quality water in this country whether that's a good use of potable supplies of water i'll leave you to think about okay so potable supplies what else sm0646: non-potable supplies [laughter] nm0638: which you use for sm0646: er energy nm0638: yeah we've had that sm0646: we've already had er nm0638: yeah sm0646: for irrigation and nm0638: okay all right irrigation anything else we'll come on to that it's f-, further down on my list sm0647: recreation nm0638: yeah okay recreation boating and all sorts of things yeah sm0648: food source nm0638: food source fisheries sm0649: fishing nm0638: seaweeds all sorts of things yeah anything else please someone the next thing on my list what else do we use water for we drink it irrigate we produce power using it sm0650: transport nm0638: yeah okay good it's not the next thing on my list but sf0651: sanitation and removal of sewage nm0638: yeah okay anything else well i suppose that is the sort of category i was thinking of actually various industrial uses whole load of industrial uses from cooling to all sorts of things okay you mentioned irrigation we've got that hydro-electric power er transport as well as recreation i've included er sort of landscape amenity value these things are all linked anything else we've had food production anyone got anything else on their list that we haven't had sm0652: it's life-sustaining nm0638: yeah yeah i think that's quite an important thing sm0652: yeah nm0638: to put down so it yeah it's life-sustaining i've got sort of habitat and ecological value and this smudgy bit just talks about biological cycles which is your point yeah it's a it's crucial to biological cycles isn't it and it's important for habitat ecological value i know a lot of these things are are linked you mentioned food production as well as that of course it can be an important source of minerals it's an important sink for pollutants and linked to the biological cycles bit of course it's important to climate system and that's not an exhaustive list i'm sure you can think of of other things so it's a pretty valuable resource to us isn't it a pretty useful resource we'll stop for a a quick coffee break in a minute but before we do that just one area of use here which i thought might be useful to look at and that's er irrigation so here we're looking at fresh water withdrawals by region we're looking at figures for the nineteen-eighties and projections for this year two-thousand and er because the the diagram didn't have that i've just coloured in if you like the proportions that are used for different uses so I-R is the red is irrigation I- N is what's used for industrial purposes and D is what's used for domestic purposes so in Europe most water is used for industry followed by irrigation followed by domestic purposes not surprisingly in Asia the vast quantity of water is used for irrigation with a relatively small amount used for industry and domestic purposes and so on you can see the figures for yourself what's noticeable is that over the nineteen-eighties to two-thousand period there has been a pretty big increase in the amount of of water used for these various purposes again putting even greater demands on the resource base yeah remember the diagram we had increasing population increasing economic activity this is these are all signs of that and the stresses and strains that that that places on resource use on resources okay finally just something to think about i thought i'd get some pollution figures out and i i just hit on two little figures as being illustrative okay sorry and again the-, these are late nineteen-eighties figures er this is looking at faecal coliform bacteria in the water so this is looking at the levels of these bacteria per hundred millilitres of water yeah so faecal coliform bacteria coming from faeces for instance so in the U-K looking at the River Exe which is around Exeter way per hundred millilitres of water there are five- hundred-and-fifty of these bacteria per hundred millilitres of water yeah but if you looked at the Sabarmati in India and i don't know whether that's a system or a river i've no idea what that is yeah then you are looking at one- point-seven- billion of these bacteria per hundred millilitres of water so that's er a relative measure of pollution for those two s-, river systems which are being used for totally different purposes of course in totally s-, different circumstances and there's a great improvement in this river in India because it was five-point-four-billion faecal coliform bacteria per hundred millilitres of water so it's gone to er less than half about a third so all sorts of waste will be go-, will be being produced er pumped out into this into this river of course people will be washing in it er livestock would be drinking and being washed in it et cetera et cetera all sorts of activities being carried out okay but not a not a very healthy environment is it to be washing in and so on now you can imagine the health problems that accrue from that level of pollution okay thank you that's time for coffee obviously er let's just break for five minutes please because i do want to finish within half an hour or so okay so a quick comfort break for five minutes nm0638: so that was a quick look at er water resources let's have a look at er ecological resources what do we mean by ecological resources here's a little definition all plant and animal resources in terms of individuals species communities habitats and ecosystems other than those managed specifically for financial gain a slightly sort of hazy definition but in other words commercial fish farms wouldn't come into this category commercial forest plantations wouldn't i guess come into this category this time just let's start with a little bit of simple little bit of data looking at er globally threatened animal species and i've just chosen three countries three very different countries Brazil the U-K and India and these are animal species that won't include insects so Brazil some three-thousand species known of which the U-N reckoned a hundred-and-five were threatened and the i think the definition of being threatened was er extinction er likely within the next ten years unless something was done the U- K relatively speaking not so species rich for these animal species three- hundred-and-thirty-five of which sixty-six of them were considered to be threatened and India again relatively species rich over two-thousand known species of which a hundred-and-seventy-eight were thought to be threatened and i don't know what message from from this little bit of data er sort of comes across to you but one of the things that comes across to me is that here we are in in the U-K in the developed world we're always talking about er dreadful things happening in other parts of the world and the loss of species the loss of rainforest and the effect on species et cetera in Brazil but here we are with a relatively high proportion of our own animal species threatened by possible extinction so what that says to me is that maybe we ought to look at our own backyard and start doing some things in this country as well which we are of course okay so why are ecological resources important to us what's their value to us why are s-, we so worried about er species becoming extinct habitats losing habitats and so on any ideas perhaps they're not perhaps we shouldn't bother who cares who cares if these species become extinct let's not waste resources worrying about them yeah sm0653: nm0638: does it matter if some obscure species in Brazil becomes extinct sm0654: it's all to do with the natural equilibrium nm0638: okay so we're worried then that we may disrupt the environment so we're very worried about environmental stability and sustainability the assumption being that species rich ecosystems are more stable ecosystems and if you start to lose species you're disrupting the ecosystem which may lead to environmental instability of one sort or another we're not quite sure and anyway in the long term it can't be sustainable can it to keep losing species all the time that's the argument okay why else are these ecological resources valuable to us useful to us sf0655: something might have medical value nm0638: yeah okay something might have er medical value yeah we'll come on to that in a minute sm0654: part of the food chain nm0638: y-, part of the food chain in what regard sm0654: we might not directly eat it but it keeps the nutrients part of the the the food chain nm0638: yeah okay okay so it's important maybe to fish stocks or whatever yeah o-, okay yeah that's that's certainly true anything else sf0656: maintain like woodlands and grass and nm0638: yeah is that different from the en-, environmental stability do you mean something different than just environmental stability is there sf0656: no i suppose that's nm0638: okay er well maybe it's part of this the direct returns bit we get all sorts of direct returns don't we from er ecological resources so we pick berries we harvest wildlife for meat and yeah so loads of different sorts of direct returns and as well and th-, this is the thing i thought you were getting at namex was er there's a visual a landscape an amenity aspect to many of these resources game reserves bring in tourists in Kenya or wherever er and so on often you know i-, these ecosystems mean that there's a nice landscape that we enjoy and so on you talked about er advances in medicine and so on well you know these species are an important source of genetic material they're genetic reserves maybe that elusive cure for a certain disease is er you know the secret is locked up in one of these species that are threatened or maybe there's some genetic material that we can use for something else who knows i mean these days with biotechnology er who knows what's going to be possible in the future this is one of our many areas of uncertainty for resource use isn't it technology okay education and research value to us and what do you think about this economists often talk about existence value and i question whether it itself exists er the idea of existence value that a species has a value to us just because it exists doesn't matter if if it doesn't have any of these benefits necessarily but it's important sm0657: intrinsic worth nm0638: exactly has this intrinsic worth it's not because it has any real necessarily any tangible benefit to it we should keep it because it exists and we shouldn't get rid of it whether that is really just because it exists or actually whether it's because of one or more of these things yeah the possibility you know it's useful as a genetic reserve er maybe it contributes to environmental stability that's what i question i think i think probably what we're saying when we talk about existence value is that all species have a value to us because maybe it's important for environmental stability maybe in the future it could add to our direct returns maybe it could be important genetic material that we'll use in the future and so on but you will come across this this term existence value in the literature and i think in in a future session you're probably going to talk about it a little bit more with with namex okay so we've been getting into sort of looking at some data and considering the more practical aspects if you like of er natural resource use and the environment er what i want to do now is to get back to a little bit of economics because one of the things that we've nearly that that we've never actually got straight is well what sort of economic framework do we need in order for us to er decide on the best use of resources d-, i didn't give this to you last time did i no it's just a copy of the overhead that i'm going to put up in the screen in a moment and it just saves you from having to get it down lots of take-aways let's pass them along please so let me remind you about some very basic economics that hopefully you haven't forgotten but i thought i ought to remind you anyway so now what we're trying to do is determine the optimum use of a resource and we assume that our aim is to maximize the net benefit to society now we know that governments and so on don't necessarily actually have that aim but let's assume that that's what we want to do to maximize the net benefit to society from the use of our resource so on the Y-axis here we have the benefits and costs associated with using the resource in pounds on the X-axis we have the amount of the resource that we're using so if you look at the total social benefit curve yeah T-S-B total social benefit you can see that as we use more and more of the resource our total social benefit increases and increases i've assumed diminishing marginal returns in that it actually starts to tail off or diminishing utility that may not be true it could be a straight line doesn't matter for this analysis okay so the benefit increases as we use more and more of the resource here we've got the costs associated with using the resource the costs of mining it using it to produce whatever we we want from the resource energy from fossil fuels whatever and so here we have what i've called the total private cost so it's the cost to to industry of using the resource and here you can see again we've got increasing costs we we're assuming diminishing marginal returns increasing costs per unit of resource are assumed so the greatest benefit the greatest net benefit that we can achieve is the biggest difference isn't it between total social benefits and total social costs yeah that's the biggest net benefit so at this level here that is the optimum level of our resource that's the level at which we maximize the net benefit to society and if it was a private firm that we were talking about yeah that would be the profit maximizing position wouldn't it and of course the profit maximizing position is where marginal costs equal marginal benefit yeah so they're just the marginal curves straight lines in fact that go with these total curves so here we have marginal social benefit curve yeah which is declining like a demand curve and here we have the marginal private cost curve like a supply curve and here's our optimum level of resource and i've got here for example barrels of oil so at level Q that level of use of oil is where we maximize you can see here the net benefit to society and if we wanted to bring that allocation about the market would do it for us if it was a perfect market it would price these barrels of oil at P each yeah and that would be er a perfect allocation of resources maximize net benefit to society great easy the problem is as we said is that our simple economic framework has in the past failed to take account of things like environmental pollution these we said we consider as externalities to the production system so what happens if we try to take account of these externalities what we're saying then is that our private cost curve the costs of getting that oil out of the ground and the costs of getting it into a form where we can burn it in our cars and get energy for instance is actually not the true cost of using that resource because for instance our cars pollute the atmosphere and an external cost is borne by third parties maybe you or i walking along inhaling fumes and our health suffers or maybe global warming whatever so there's an external cost that falls on other people in society than the oil companies and just the people that drive their cars there are other people that bear the costs as well so these external costs then have to be taken into account in order to get the total social cost of resource use rather than just the private cost so this green curve suitably green curve here has taken account of the negative externalities like environmental pollution associated with using the resource and you can see the cost curve has shifted upwards now if we use this cost curve instead of the private cost curve to look at the optimum use of our resource you can see that the optimum changes and net benefit to society from using the resource is actually achieved at a lower level of resource use here than previously and if we look at the marginal cost and marginal benefit curves we can see that perhaps even more clearly so now we have the marginal social cost curve added to this diagram same diagram as before we've just added this green marginal social cost curve yeah which is the slope isn't it these marginal curves are the slope the rate of change of these total curves yeah so that's the slope of this curve yeah so you can see that the slope is increasing and hence this marginal social cost curve is increasing so the optimum use of our resource that was at Q now that we've taken account of the negative environmental externalities associated with the use of this resource our optimum is actually not at Q yeah we've been using too much of this resource it's actually here at Q-dashed in green so in order this diagram is telling us in order to maximize the net benefit to society we need to cut back on current usage of oil and use a little bit less of it and again that point is shown by where the marginal social cost curve cuts the marginal social benefit curve the other thing this diagram tells you is that where the price of oil before was price P if you want to bring about this environmentally-friendly maximum benefit to society you've got to change the price of oil and the price that'll bring about this level of resource use again is where the marginal curves cross which this time now is P-dashed so this is telling you if you want to bring about this allocation of resources within society you're going to have to increase the price of oil to consumers from P to P-dashed because the market won't do that the market will set the price at P so one of the things for instance that you might want to do is to place an environmental tax on oil so that the price people pay isn't P but it's P-dashed and that's is one of the things that namex is going to talk to you about er in future weeks are there any questions about that diagram i i think it's fairly simple and straightforward you should have seen diagrams like this before but are there any questions because it's important that y-, that you understand it at this simplistic stage before you do any further theory okay i can see you're totally exhausted from the experience of doing a bit more economic theory so i think let's call it a day shall we okay and next week will be will be namex